U.S. flag

An official website of the United States government

The .gov means it’s official. Federal government websites often end in .gov or .mil. Before sharing sensitive information, make sure you’re on a federal government site.

The site is secure. The https:// ensures that you are connecting to the official website and that any information you provide is encrypted and transmitted securely.

  • Publications
  • Account settings

Preview improvements coming to the PMC website in October 2024. Learn More or Try it out now .

  • Advanced Search
  • Journal List
  • HHS Author Manuscripts

Logo of nihpa

Trade and Geography in the Spread of Islam *

Stelios michalopoulos.

† Brown University, Department of Economics, 64 Waterman st., Robinson Hall, Providence, RI 02912, USA, CEPR, and NBER, ude.nworb@olahcims .

Alireza Naghavi

‡ University of Bologna. Department of Economics, Piazza Scaravilli 2, 40126 Bologna, Italy, [email protected]

Giovanni Prarolo

§ University of Bologna. Department of Economics, Piazza Scaravilli 2, 40126 Bologna, Italy, [email protected] .

Associated Data

In this study we explore the historical determinants of contemporary Muslim representation. Motivated by a plethora of case studies and historical accounts among Islamicists stressing the role of trade for the adoption of Islam, we construct detailed data on pre-Islamic trade routes, harbors, and ports to determine the empirical regularity of this argument. Our analysis – conducted across countries and across ethnic groups within countries – establishes that proximity to the pre-600 CE trade network is a robust predictor of today’s Muslim adherence in the Old World. We also show that Islam spread successfully in regions that are ecologically similar to the birthplace of the religion, the Arabian Peninsula. Namely, territories characterized by a large share of arid and semiarid regions dotted with few pockets of fertile land are more likely to host Muslim communities. We discuss the various mechanisms that may give rise to the observed pattern.

“ O you who believe! Eat not up your property among yourselves unjustly except it be a trade amongst you, by mutual consent. And do not kill yourselves (nor kill one another). Surely, Allah is Most Merciful to you.” The Noble Qur’an (Hilali-Khan translation), Surah An-Nisa’, 4:29 1

1. Introduction

Religion is significantly correlated with a range of economie and politicai outcomes both within and across countries. 2 This can, perhaps, be linked to the fact that religious people tend to be more trusting in general ( Guiso, Sapienza, and Zingales, 2003 ). Given the importance of religion in society, a natural question to ask is what factors contributed to the distribution of religions around the globe that we see today.

In this study, we focus on the spread of one religion – Islam. There has been growing interest in Muslim societies in recent years amongst economists and political scientists, see for example, Blydes (2014) , Campante and Yanagizawa-Drott (2015) , Clingingsmith, Khwaja, and Kremer (2009) , Jha (2013) , and Kuran (2004) . Our analysis investigates the role that ancient trade routes have played in facilitating the spread of Islam. Motivated by numerous case studies on the historical relationship between trade and Islam, we construct detailed data on pre-Islamic trade routes, ports, and harbors. Proximity to the pre-600 CE trade network is a robust predictor of today’s Muslim adherence in the Old World. We also show that Islam spread successfully in regions that are ecologically similar to the birthplace of the religion, the Arabian Peninsula.

The empirical analysis establishes that countries located closer to historical trade routes are more likely to be Muslim. We then investigate whether this empirical regularity holds at the more disaggregated level of ethnic homelands within countries. Exploiting within-country variation has straightforward advantages. First, it allows us to test in a sharper manner whether differences in proximity to pre-Islamic trade routes are meaningful predictors of local adherence to Islam. Second, leveraging within contemporary-state variation in Muslim representation mitigates concerns related to the endogeneity of current political boundaries. Modern states, arguably, have affected religious affiliation in a multitude of ways including state-sponsored religion. As such, it is crucial to account for these nationwide histories.

These findings are in line with a rich body of earlier work by prominent Islamicists including Lapidus (2002) , Berkey (2003) , and Lewis (1993) , who have extensively discussed the role of long-distance trade, noting both the diffusion of Muslims along trade routes ( Geertz, 1968 ; Lewis, 1980 ; Trimingham, 1962 ) and the importance that Islamic scriptures confer on trade-related matters ( Cohen, 1971 ; Hiskett, 1984 ; Last, 1979 ). An innovation of Islam was the practice of direct trade, where Muslim merchants personally carried goods over long distances along the trade routes rather than relying on intermediaries. For example, the acceptance of Islam in most of Inner Asia, Southeast Asia, and Sub-Saharan Africa is known to have occurred primarily through contacts with Muslim merchants ( Insoll, 2003 ; Lapidus, 2002 ; Levtzion, 1979 ). In addition, the highly personal practice of exchange created preference for Muslims to conduct trade with co-religionists (Chaudhuri, 1995; Kuran and Lustig, 2012 ). Therefore, merchants converting to Islam enjoyed substantial externalities like access to the Muslim trade network, steady trade flows, and a reduction in transaction costs. In Section 2 we provide a brief overview illustrating the role of trade in the Islamization process in various parts of the Old World.

Although the primary contribution of this study is to establish how proximity to pre-Islamic trade routes has influenced the distribution of Muslim communities in the Old World, we also explore whether the ecological similarity to the Arabian peninsula of a given region predicts the presence of Muslim communities. But which are the salient geographic features of the cradle of Islam? The Arabian peninsula has a distinct geography, mainly consisting of desert and semi-arid landscapes with a few regions of moderate fertility such as today’s Yemen and other scattered oases in the interior. On the eve of Islam, frankincense, myrrh, vine, dyes, and dates were produced in these fertile pockets ( Ibrahim, 1990 ). To capture this distinct landscape, we construct for each country/ethnic homeland the Gini coefficient of land suitability for agriculture and show that ecological similarity to the Arabian Peninsula (reflected in the degree of inequality in the potential for farming across regions) increases Muslim representation.

We discuss various explanations consistent with this less-well-known fact and show that groups residing along geographically unequal territories have a particular production structure (both historically and today) with pasture dominating the semi-arid landscape and farming taking place in the few relatively fertile regions. These differences in the underlying productive endowments may generate gains from specialization and provide a basis for trade as a means of subsistence. This is indeed the case for a cross-section of ethnographic societies we examine. So, to the extent that trade is likely to flourish when the parties involved adhere to a common code of exchange, the trade-promoting institutional framework of Islam would find likely converts across such territories.

A complementary interpretation links geographic inequality to social inequality and predation and echoes Ibn Khaldun (1377) , one of the greatest philosophers of the Muslim world, who observed that a crucial factor for understanding Muslim history is the central social conflict between the primitive Bedouin and the urban society (“town” versus “desert”). The argument is that long-distance trade opportunities confer differential gains to populations residing in the relatively more fertile regions, fostering predatory behavior from the poorly endowed ones. Along the same lines, contemporary scholars have noted that when farmers and herders coexisted in absence of an institutional framework coordinating their activities, their interactions were often conflictual, disrupting trade flows across these territories ( Richerson, 1996 ). We conjecture that Islam with its redistributive economic principles was a unifying force aimed at reining in the underlying inequality in exchange for security for the trading caravans ( Michalopoulos, Naghavi, and Prarolo, 2016 ). The premise that geographie inequality becomes more salient when long-distance trade opportunities arise generates an auxiliary prediction. Namely, the intensity of adoption of Islam across unequally endowed regions should increase with proximity to trade routes. This prediction is borne out in the data.

Our study belongs to a wider literature in economics that explores the interplay between the economic and political environment and (religious) beliefs and rules. Contributions include works by Greif (1994) , Benabou and Tirole (2001) , Botticini and Eckstein (2005 , 2007 ), Cervellati and Sunde (2017) , Guiso, Sapienza, and Zingales (2016) , Platteau (2008 , 2011 ), Rubin (2009) , Becker and Woessmann (2009) , and Greif and Tabellini (2010) . Moreover, by focusing on the spread of a particular religion, our work is closely related to that of Cantoni (2012) who explores how proximity to Wittemberg, the birthplace of Martin Luther, influenced the diffusion of Protestantism. The evidence provided on the consistent geographic pattern followed by the Muslim world also makes contact with the studies by Engerman and Sokoloff (1997 , 2002 ) and Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (2001 , 2002 ), among others, that stress the role of geography in shaping institutional outcomes.

The rest of the paper is organized as follows. In Section 2 we provide a historical narrative of the significance of trade for the spread of Islam. In Section 3 , we discuss the data and present the empirical analysis conducted across countries and ethnic groups. In Section 4 , we dig deeper into what distance to trade routes and geographic inequality reflect and outline possible explanations consistent with the uncovered evidence. Section 5 summarizes and discusses avenues for future research.

2. The Spread of Islam along Historical Trade Routes

Islam has spread at a breathless pace since the time of Muhammad. Nevertheless, the mode of expansion has differed across time and space ranging from conquests, to trade, to proselytization and migrations. During the early phase, Islam expanded mainly through conquests within a certain radius around Mecca. The initial military conquests, even if they did not entail forced conversion, eventually resulted in Muslim-majority populations occupying large swaths of land. These areas overlap with contemporary countries close to Mecca including the entire Arab World in the Middle East and North Africa, Iran, Afghanistan, and Pakistan, and slightly further away in Uzbekistan and Turkmenistan. The territories featured important trade hubs during the pre-Islamic era, particularly those along the Silk Road in Asia and the Red Sea in North Africa. Most of these lands were part of the Persian Empire, which was the largest and most important empire of the time to be conquered and concede to Islam. Famous trade hubs along the routes of the Persian Empire were Rey (in Iran), Samarkand and Bukhara (in Uzbekistan), and Merv (in Turkmenistan).

The process of Islamization farther away from the birthplace of Islam was intimately linked to trade. The Islamic world came to dominate the network of the most lucrative international trade routes that connected Asia to Europe (and by sea to North Africa). With full Muslim control of the western half of the Silk Road by mid-8th century, any long-distance exchange had to traverse Muslim lands, giving trade a central role in the further propagation of the religion. Muslim merchants carried the message of Islam wherever they traveled. This was possible because of the Muslim practise of “direct” trade, one of the most remarkable innovations of Islam. Prior to Muslim conquests, trade was conducted by a network of local merchants who traded exclusively in their homelands. In other words, they played the role of intermediary agents with goods (often spices) being transported from one carrier to another by short journeys, creating a trade-relay. Muslims instead did not rely on intermediaries and personally travelled the entire length of the journey, crucial for the diffusion of the religion along the trade routes and at the destination. The spread of Islam was hence greatly enhanced by social contact as a consequence of trade ( Miller, 1969 ; Wood, 2003 ).

On the receiving end, the new religion appealed to the local merchants because it legitimized their economic base more than most belief systems present at that time. Merchants converting to Islam had clear advantages including (i) cooperation within the Muslim trading network, (ii) valuable contacts to expand their trade, and (iii) rules governing commercial activities naturally favoring Muslims over non-Muslims ( Sinor, 1990 ; Foltz, 1999 ).

Proselytization was a third factor that inffuenced the spread of Islam across locations most distant to Mecca. Trade routes were also important in this process as the charismatic Sufi preachers travelled along these routes to perform missionary activities. Finally, migration of Muslims (again through trade routes) and their inter-marriages at the destination also contributed to the spread of Islam along the trade routes distant from Mecca.

2.1. The Adoption of Islam by Ethnie Groups in the Vicinity of Trade Routes

The historical accounts linking trade routes and Muslim adherence across countries are indicative of their importance for the spread of Islam. Nevertheless, given the power of the state to inffuence its religious composition, one may wonder whether a similar nexus between proximity to trade hubs and Muslim representation exists within countries that are not religiously homogeneous. In what follows, we review the historical record on the emergence of Islam for specific countries with varying religious diversity including China, Tanzania, Mali (the location of the former Ghana Empire), Indonesia, and India. A systematic empirical analysis at the ethnic group level for each of these countries is relegated to Section 3.3 .

Figures 1a, 1b, 1c, 1d, and 1e provide snapshots of pre-Islamic trade routes along with contemporary Muslim representation for groups located in these five regions making apparent the link between the two (see Section 3.1 below for a description of the underlying data).

An external file that holds a picture, illustration, etc.
Object name is nihms-1013856-f0001.jpg

Figure 1 portrays Muslim adherence at the ethnic group level and historical trade routes within five countries (1a: China, 1b: Mali, 1c: Tanzania, 1d: Indonesia and 1e: India). Muslim adherence is represented in quintiles at the level of ethnic group, where actual homelands are from the Ethnologue version 15 and data on religious affiliation from the World Religion Database. Darker shades represent higher Muslim shares in the population. In Figures 1a, 1c, and 1e the trade routes are depicted as thick, black-and-white dashed lines and correspond to pre-600 CE. These routes are digitized from Brice and Kennedy (2001) . The ancient ports and harbors, depicted as circled stars, are from Arthur de Graauw (2014) . In figure 1b trade routes are relative to 900 AD, while in figures 1c and 1d ports in year 600 CE (1800 CE) are represented with circled stars (circled dots). Country borders are represented with a thin dashed grey line.

2.2. Inner Asia

By the 8th century, Islam was no longer the religion of only the Arab world and had expanded geographical borders along the Silk Road. Conversions were often a result of economic considerations and the financial benefits afforded to those joining the Ummah. Even among the conquered people in Central Asia, Islam continued to gain a hearing without coercion as merchants spread the religion. Muslim traders traveled as far as the capital of the Tang dynasty, Chang’an, in the Chinese Empire. The 9th century saw the rise of Islamic kingdoms in Central Asia, especially the Samanid Empire, the first Persian dynasty after the Arab conquests. The Islamization of the nomadic Turkic peoples of Central and Inner Asia occurred during the 10th century along the trade routes. This process has been linked mainly to their participation in the oasis-based Silk Road trade and was accelerated by the conversion and the expansion of three Turkic Muslim dynasties of the Karakhanids, the Ghaznavids, and the Seljuks ( Meri and Bacharach, 2006 ).

The major ethnic groups close to trade routes with a substantial Muslim representation in this region are the Uyghurs, the Hui, the Kazakhs, the Kyrgyz, and the Tajiks. These ethnic groups also exist within China today and comprise the Muslim minority in the country. They are all located around Xianjiang, a vast region of deserts and mountains along the Silk Road in Northwest China.

The Uyghurs are one of the largest ethnic groups in Inner Asia, and their Islamization dates back to the Karakhanids in early 10th century, the first Turkic dynasty to convert to the new religion. The core of the Uyghurs’ homeland was Kashgar, an oasis city located in the West of China near the current-day border of Tajikistan and Kyrgyzstan, which historically served as a strategic trade hub between China, the Middle East, and Europe ( Roemer, 2000 ). The Hui people are another Muslim Chinese minority historically connected to Muslim merchants travelling along the Silk Road. Besides Xianjiang, they also live farther east in Central China. A cluster of this group can be found today in Xi’an, where they form the majority of a large Muslim community (the dark spot in the center of China in Figure 1a ). Xi’an was the first city in China where Islam was introduced. ( Soucek, 2000 ). The longest segment of the Silk Road runs across the Central Asia and Kazakhstan. The religion practiced by the majority of Kazakhs is Islam since its introduction in the region by the Arabs during the 9th century. The Kyrgyz tribes also adopted Islam as Muslim traders and then Sufi missionaries began to move out from scattered towns to the nomadic steppes, spreading Islam among the tribal groups. They are known to have adopted Islam between the 8th and 12th centuries. The Tajiks on the other hand, started converting to Islam in the late 11th century ( Minahan, 2014 ).

2.3. East and West Africa

Islam spread through the well-established trade routes of the east coast of Africa via merchants. The earliest records for trade in East Africa indicate Greco-Roman trade down the Red Sea and along the Somali coast to the Tanzanian coast. This was followed by the trade of frankincense, myrrh, and spices with the Persian Gulf from the 2nd to the 5th century CE. Soon Zanzibar Island also became a trade hub and remained so until the 9th century CE, when Bantu traders settled on the Kenyan-Tanzanian coast and joined the Indian Ocean trade networks interacting with the Somali and Arab proselytizers. Shanga, an early Swahili town on Pate Island in the Lamu Archipelago, is a good example of early influence through Muslim traders as they built the first small wooden mosque in the region around 850 CE ( Shillington, 2005 ). Islam was established on the Southeast coast soon after, and eventually a full-scale prosperous Muslim dynasty known for trading gold and slaves was established at Kilwa on the coast of modern Tanzania. By the 11th century CE, several settlements down the east coast were equipped with mosques, and Islam emerged as a unifying force on the coast to form a distinct Swahili identity ( Trimingham, 1964 ).

Historical accounts suggest that the early penetration of Islam was even more effective along the caravan routes of West Africa. Trans-Saharan trade started on a regular basis during the 4th century and presents a clear example of subsistence from trade between the people of the Sahara, forest, Sahel, and savanna ( Boahen, Ajayi, and Tidy, 1966 ). While present since 500 CE, the significance of the trans-Saharan trade routes rose and declined over time depending on the empire in power and the security that could be maintained along the routes ( Devisse, 1988 ). Islam was introduced through Muslim traders along several major trade routes that connected Africa below the Sahara with the Mediterranean Middle East, such as Sijilmasa to Awdaghust and Ghadames to Gao. Muslims crossed the Sahara into West Africa trading salt, horses, dates, and camels for gold, timber, and foodstuff from the ancient Ghana empire. The trade-friendly elements of Islam, such as credit or contract law, together with the information networks it helped create, facilitated long-distance trade. By the 10th century, merchants to the south of the trade routes had converted to Islam. In the 11th century CE the rulers began to convert. The first Muslim ruler in the region was the king of Gao, around the year 1000 CE. The Kanem empire (the Kanuri people), located at the southern end of the trans-Saharan trade route between Tripoli and the region of Lake Chad, followed after being exposed to Islam through North African traders, Berbers, and Arabs ( Trimingham, 1962 ; Levtzion and Pouwels, 2000 ; Robinson, 2004 ).

2.4. South and Southeast Asia

There is ample historical evidence indicating that Arabs and Muslims interacted with India from the very early days of Islam, although trade relations had existed since ancient times. Malabar and Kochi were two important princely states on the western coast of India where Arabs and Persians found fertile ground for their trade activities. The trade on the Malabar coast prospered due to the local production of pepper and other spices. Islam was first introduced to India by the newly converted Arab traders reaching the western coast of India (Malabar and the Konkan-Gujarat region) during the 7th century CE ( Elliot and Dowson, 1867 ; Makhdum, 2006 ; Rawlinson, 2003 ).

Cheraman Juma Masjid in Kerala is thought to be the first mosque in India. It was built towards the end of Muhammad’s lifetime during the reign of the last ruler of the Chera dynasty, who converted to Islam and facilitated the proliferation of Islam in Malabar. The 8th century CE marked the start of a period of expansion of Muslim commerce along all major routes in the Indian Ocean, suggesting that the Islamic influence during this period was essentially one of commercial nature. Initially settling in Konkan and Gujarat, the Persians and Arabs extended their trading bases and settlements to southern India and Sri Lanka by the 8th century CE, and to the Coromandel coast in the 9th century CE. These ports helped develop maritime trade links between the Middle East and Southeast Asia during the 10th century CE ( Wink, 1990 ).

The people of the Malay world have been active participants in trade and maritime activities for over a thousand years. Their settlements along major rivers and coastal areas were important means of contact with traders from the rest of the world. The strategic location of the Malay Archipelago at the crossroad between the Indian Ocean and East Asia, and in the middle of the China-India trade route, aided the rapid development of trade in the region ( Wade, 2009 ). In particular, the Srivijaya kingdom (7th −13th century CE) on the straits of Malacca attracted ships from China, India, and Arabia plying the China-India trade routes by ensuring safe passage through the Straits of Malacca ( Andaya and Andaya, 1982 ).

Similar to those in Africa, rulers in Southeast Asia often converted to Islam through the influence of Muslim merchants who set up or conducted business there. While the landed Hindu-Buddhists were content to let the trade come to them, the Muslim merchants, lacking a fixed land base, made their profits from trade at the location of exchange. Consequently, the people of Southeast Asia began to accept Islam and create Muslim towns and kingdoms. By the late 13th century CE, the kingdom of Pasai in northern Sumatra had converted to Islam. At the same time, the collapse of Srivijayan power at the end of the 13th century CE drew foreign traders to the harbors on the northern Sumatran shores of the Bay of Bengal, safe from the pirate lairs at the southern end of the Strait of Malacca ( Houben, 2003 ; Ricklefs, 1991 ). Around 1400 CE, a new kingdom was established in Malacca (on the north shore of the Malacca Strait). The rulers of Malacca soon accepted Islam in order to attract Muslim and Javanese traders to their port by providing a common culture and offering legal security under Islamic law ( Holt, Lambton, and Lewis, 1970 ; Esposito, 1999 ). Finally, the Bugis, an ethnic group along Java’s northern coast adopted Islam later in the 16th century CE when Muslim proselytizers from West Sumatra came in contact with the people of this region who conducted trade ( Mattulada, 1983 ).

3. Empirical section

3.1. the data sources.

The historical overview vividly illustrates the importance of pre-existing trade routes for the diffusion of Islam but also suggests the beneficial impact of Islam on the further expansion of the trade network. To make sure we capture the first part of this two-way relationship, we construct our main explanatory variable by measuring the distance between the relevant unit of analysis (a country or an ethnic homeland) and the closest historical trade route or port before 600 CE, reflecting the structure of trade flows already present in the Old World in the eve of Islam. 3

The location of trade routes is outlined in Brice and Kennedy (2001) whereas the location of ancient ports and harbors is taken from the work of De Graauw, Maione-Downing, and McCormick (2014) who collected and identified their precise locations. The result is an impressive list of approximately 2, 900 ancient ports and harbors mentioned in the writings of 66 ancient authors and a few modern authors, including the Barrington Atlas. We complement the pre-600 CE routes mapped in Brice and Kennedy (2001) with information on the Roman roads identified in the Barrington Atlas ( McCormick, et al., 2013 ). Finally, we also extend the trade network up to 1800 CE, digitizing the relevant information from Brice and Kennedy (2001) , and supplementing it with routes within Europe, Southeast Asia, West Africa, and China mapped in O’Brien (1999) during the same time period. We expect these data to be useful to other researchers. See Figures 2a and 2b for the reconstruction of the pre-Islamic and pre-1800 CE trade network, respectively.

An external file that holds a picture, illustration, etc.
Object name is nihms-1013856-f0003.jpg

Figure 2a (2b) shows the Old World network of Roman roads (from the Barrington Atlas), ancient ports and harbours (from Arthur de Graauw, 2014 ) and trade routes (from Brice and Kennedy, 2001 ) in 600 AD (1800 AD).

In the cross-country analysis, the dependent variable employed is the fraction of Muslims in the population as early as 1900 CE reported by Barrett, Kurian, and Johnson (2001) . For the ethnic group analysis, the dependent variable is the fraction of Muslims and of other religious denominations in 2005 from the World Religion Database (WRD). 4 These estimates are extracted from the World Christian Database and are subsequently adjusted based on three sources of religious affiliation: census data, demographic and health surveys, and population survey data. 5 In absence of historical estimates of Muslim representation at an ethnic group level, we are constrained in using contemporary data. Reassuringly, country-level Muslim representation derived from the group-specific estimates of the WRD are highly correlated (0.93) with the respective country statistics on Muslim adherence in 1900 CE.

Information on the location of ethnic groups’ homelands is available from the World Language Mapping System (WLMS) database. This dataset maps the locations of the language groups covered in the 15th edition of the Ethnologue (2005) database. The location of each ethnic group is identified by a polygon. Each of these polygons delineates the traditional homeland of an ethnic group; populations away from their homelands (e.g., in cities, refugee populations, etc.) are not mapped. Also, the WLMS (2006) does not attempt to map immigrant languages. Finally, ethnic groups of unknown location, widespread ethnicities (i.e., groups whose boundaries coincide with a country’ boundaries) and extinct languages are not mapped and, thus, not considered in the empirical analysis. The matching between the WLMS (2006) and the WRD is done using the unique Ethnologue identifier for each ethnic group within a country. 6

To capture how similar the ecology of a given region is to that of the Arabian Peninsula, we construct the distribution of land quality and, in turn, the Gini coefficient of regional land potential for agriculture across countries and homelands. Under the assumption that land quality dictates the productive capabilities of a given region, populations on fertile areas would engage in farming whereas pastoralism would be the norm in poorly endowed regions (see more on this in Section 4 ). In the absence of historical data on land quality, we use contemporary disaggregated data on the suitability of land for agriculture to proxy for regional productive endowments. The global data on current land quality for agriculture were assembled by Ramankutty et al. (2002) to investigate the effect of future climate change on contemporary agricultural suitability and have been used extensively in the recent literature in historical comparative development. Each observation takes a value between 0 and 1 and represents the probability that a particular grid cell may be cultivated. 7

Finally, we combine anthropological information on ethnic groups from Murdock (1967) with the Ethnologue (2005) , enabling us to examine the pre-colonial societal and economic traits of Muslim groups. We discuss these two datasets in more detail as we introduce them to our analysis.

3.2. Cross-Country Analysis

We start by investigating the relationship between distance to trade routes in the Old World and Muslim adherence across modern-day countries. The cross-country summary statistics and the corresponding correlation matrix of the variables of interest are reported in Appendix Table 1 .

To estimate how proximity to trade routes shapes Muslim adherence we adopt the following OLS specification:

where % Muslim 1900 i is the fraction of the population in country i adhering to Islam in 1900 CE. 8

In Column 1 of Table 1 , we report the univariate relationship between distance from trade routes and Muslim adherence. The coefficient is economically and statistically significant. Across modern-day countries variation in the distance to pre-Islamic trade routes accounts for roughly 9% of the observed variation in Muslim representation. The magnitude of the estimated coefficient, moreover, suggests that a country located 1, 000 kilometers farther from the 600 CE trade routes has 15% lower Muslim representation. Naturally, one may wonder whether this association remains robust to other possible determinants of Muslim adherence that may be correlated to distance to trade routes. In Column 2, we add a series of distance terms that may be potential confounders. The literature reviewed in Section 2 unequivocally suggests that proximity to Mecca is likely to be a strong predictor for the spread of Islam, and this is indeed what we find. The precisely estimated coefficient on distance to Mecca suggests that countries that are 1, 000 kilometers closer to Mecca see a 7% increase in their Muslim share, and countries further away from the equator are less likely to be Muslim. Distance to the coast by itself does not significantly affect Muslim representation. These three additional location attributes significantly increase the predictive power of the empirical model, the R 2 jumps to 23%; nevertheless, the coefficient of interest only slightly declines and remains precisely estimated.

Table 1 reports OLS estimates associating the share of Muslims with geographical variables. Observations are at the level of countries, the sample is the Old World (Europe, Asia and Africa). In all specifications the dependent variable is the share of Muslims in 1900 from McCleary and Barro (2005). All specifications include the constant (not reported) and column (5) includes a set of continental effects.

The Supplementary Appendix gives detailed definitions, data sources and summary statistics for all variables. Standard errors in parentheses are robust to heteroskedasticity. ***, **, and * indicate statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

In the rest of the Columns of Table 1 , we add additional geographic variables. The goal is twofold. First, to make sure that the uncovered relationship between distance to trade routes and Muslim adherence is not driven by some other geographic factor, and second, and perhaps more importantly, in doing so, we attempt to shed light on the geographie covariates of Islam. Given the recent interest among growth economists on the environmental determinants of comparative development, the list of potential geographic candidates is long. So, our choice of variables is disciplined in the following manner. Since we are interested in exploring whether a given region’s ecological similarity to the Arabian peninsula predicts the presence of Muslim communities, we construct the Gini coefficient of land suitability for agriculture using the data from Ramankutty et al. (2002) .

The following example may help illustrate the type of geographies that this measure reflects. Uzbekistan and Poland are both equally close to pre-Islamic trade routes (approximately 190 kilometers) but have very different ecologies. On the one hand, less than 10% of Uzbekistan’s territory lies in river valleys and oases that serve as cultivable land, whereas the rest of the country is dominated by the Kyzyl Kum desert and mountains. In our data, the Gini coefficient of land quality is estimated to be 0.59 (82nd percentile) with an average land quality of 0.25. On the other hand, Poland has a much more homogeneous geography in terms of farming potential with a Gini coefficient of 0.16 (30th percentile) and an average land suitability of 0.56. As of 1900 CE, Uzbekistan was 98% Muslim whereas there were no Muslims in Poland. These stark geographic differences across Muslim and non-Muslim countries are readily visible in the our sample. Out of the 127 countries in the Old World, those 35 (92) that have a Muslim absolute majority (minority) have median land quality equal to 0.22 (0.50) and median Gini coefficient in land quality of 0.54 (0.20). In Column 4 of Table 1 , we add both of these geographic indexes in logs to our benchmark specification. The estimated coefficient on proximity to pre-Islamic trade routes remains qualitatively and quantitatively intact. Moreover, the estimates suggest that low land suitability for agriculture and high inequality in the spatial distribution of this scarce factor are strongly predictive of the presence of Muslims across countries. Adding these two features in the regression increases the R 2 by 25 percentage points revealing the importance of geographic features in the spread of Islam. One may naturally wonder what potential mechanisms are behind this strong associations. We will return to this question in Section 4 .

In the rest of the columns in Table 1 , we check the robustness of our findings. Specifically, in Column 4, we add four more geographic traits. The log area of each country, the log of terrain ruggedness, an indicator reflecting the presence of a desert, and an indicator reflecting whether a country has any irrigation potential. 9 These geographic variables are chosen for the following reasons. First, Bulliet (1975) observed that Arab armies had a comparative advantage over desert terrain. In our sample of 127 countries, 38 feature some desert. Moreover, Bentzen, Kaarsen, and Wingender (2016) show that Muslim countries have higher irrigation potential and the latter may be correlated both with proximity to trade routes and inequality in the spatial distribution of land quality across cells within a country. Finally, ruggedness is controlled for as it is likely that more rugged countries limit the ability of foreign powers to penetrate them, and it also seems plausible that ruggedness is associated with the quality of land and trade routes ( Chaney and Hornbeck, 2016 ). Adding these controls neither changes the magnitude nor the precision of the estimates of our main explanatory variables. Among these new covariates, the only consistent predictor of Muslim representation is the potential for irrigation in line with Bentzen, Kaarsen, and Wingender (2016) . Finally, in Column 5 we add continental fixed effects to account for the broad geographic and historical differences between the continental masses finding similar results. Figure 3 plots non-parametrically the relationship between Muslim representation and distance to the pre-Islamic trade network after partialling out the covariates included in Column 5. 10

An external file that holds a picture, illustration, etc.
Object name is nihms-1013856-f0004.jpg

3.3. Cross-Ethnic-Group Analysis

The evidence so far reveals a strong cross-country association between Muslim representation and proximity to pre-Islamic trade routes as well as an unequal distribution of land endowments. However, the spread of Islam is a historical process that predated the emergence of modern nation states. Moreover, the historical record is replete with examples of current countries actively influencing their religious composition by promoting or demoting specific religious identities. Would the cross-country patterns survive if we were to account for the idiosyncratic historical legacies of contemporary states? To answer this we look at the religious affiliations of ethnic groups within countries. This allows us to control for country-specific constants and thus produce reliable estimates of the impact of trade routes on Muslim adherence.

In Appendix Table 2 Panel A, we report the summary statistics of the main variables employed in the cross-ethnic-group analysis. 11 An average ethnic group in the Old World has 21% of its population adhering to Islam in 2005, is 5, 230 kilometers from Mecca, and 1, 345 kilometers from trade routes before 600 CE. Appendix Table 2 Panel B shows the raw correlations among the main variables of interest. Ethnic-specific Muslim representation is negatively related to distance to Mecca (−0.24) and distance to trade routes in 600 CE (−0.22).

We adopt the following specification:

where δ c represents the country-specific fixed effects. 12

Before showing the results for all groups across the Old World, and motivated by the historical accounts summarized in Section 2 , in Table 2 we report bivariate regressions linking distance to pre-600 CE trade routes to contemporary Muslim adherence across linguistic groups within specific countries. In Columns 1, 2, and 3, we look at the religious composition of language groups in China, Mali (the location of the ancient Ghana empire), and Tanzania, respectively. Within each of these countries with varied historical legacies, and as foreshadowed by our early discussion, proximity to trade routes is a systematic predictor of Muslim communities. In Column 4, we focus on Indonesia, the country with the largest Muslim population worldwide. Across the 615 linguistic groups mapped by the Ethnologue, variation in the proximity of these homelands to pre-Islamic trade routes accounts for almost a quarter (22%) of the observed variation in contemporary Muslim adherence. In Column 5 we show that a similar pattern holds for India, a country where although Muslims are a minority they nevertheless represent the third-largest Muslim population across countries. In what follows, instead of showing country-specific estimates we use the entire sample of linguistic groups across the Old World to assess this link.

Table 2 reports OLS estimates associating the share of Muslims with distance from trade routes in 600AD in selected countries, at the level of ethnic group. In all specifications the dependent variable is the share of Muslims in 2005 at ethnic group level from the World Religion Database. All specifications include a constant (not reported).

To facilitate comparison across the different levels of analysis, the layout of Table 3A mimics that of Table 1 . The pattern found in the cross-country analysis resurfaces in the cross-ethnicity sample. The difference between Columns 1 and 2 in Table 3A is that in the latter we include country-specific constants. By doing so, the coefficient on the proximity to pre-Islamic trade routes increases considerably. Within modern-day countries, ethnic groups whose historical homelands are closer to the trade routes before 600 CE experience a significant boost in their Muslim representation. Namely, a 1, 000-kilometer increase in the former decreases Muslim representation by 17 percentage points. Columns 3 to 5 confirm the pattern obtained in Columns 2 to 4 of Table 1 . Regions closer to pre-Islamic trade routes, characterized by overall low land quality interspersed with pockets of fertile land are more likely to be populated by Muslim communities today. One noteworthy difference between the two levels of aggregation is that in the cross-group sample proximity to Mecca is now a reliable and precisely estimated correlate of Muslim adherence. In Figure 4 , we graph non-parametrically the association between Muslim representation across groups and distance to the pre-Islamic routes after partialling out all covariates included in Column 5 of Table 3A .

An external file that holds a picture, illustration, etc.
Object name is nihms-1013856-f0005.jpg

Table 3A reports OLS estimates associating the share of Muslims with geographical variables. Observations are at the level of ethnic group, the sample is the Old World (Europe, Asia and Africa). In all specifications the dependent variable is the share of Muslims in 2005 from World Religion Database. Column (1) includes the constant (not reported), while the remaining columns include a set of country fixed effects.

The Supplementary Appendix gives detailed definitions, data sources and summary statistics for all variables. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the country level. ***, **, and * indicate statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

Groups of people coming under the direct rule of a Muslim empire might face incentives for converting to Islam related to social mobility ( Bulliet, 1979 ), a career within a Muslim bureaucracy ( Eaton, 1996 ), or lower tax rates (Chaney, 2008). For example, the lower tax rates granted to Muslims over non-Muslims within Muslim Empires or the status achieved by switching to the ruler’s religion might differentially affect conversion rates. Likewise, instances of forced conversion, religious persecution during the Muslim expansion, or Arab migration movements within the Muslim empires might have shaped the observed religious affiliation. Hence, in Columns 1 and 2 of Table 3B , we divide the ethnic groups based on whether they have been within a Muslim empire as classified by Iyigun (2010) . An ethnic group is considered to be outside a Muslim empire if the country to which it belongs today has never been part of a Muslim empire. Both the negative relationship of Muslim adherence and distance to trade routes and the positive link with geographic inequality remain significant outside the former Muslim empires.

Table 3B reports OLS estimates associating the share of Muslims with geographical variables. Observations are at the level of ethnic group, the samples are partitions of the Old World (Europe, Asia and Africa). In Column 1 (2) the sample includes ethnic groups within (outside) the Muslim empires as classified by Iyigun (2010). In Column 3 (4) the sample is restricted to ethnic groups outside the Muslim empires where the dominant religion during the expansion of Islam was a non-monotheistic (monotheistic) one. In all specifications the dependent variable is the share of Muslims in 2005 from the World Religion Database.

It is clear that Europe traded with the Muslim world for centuries without large-scale conversions, indicating that there may be other factors at play than just access to the Islamic trade networks. Considering that monotheism was an attractive ideology compared to polytheism, regions outside the Muslim empires where monotheism was already present should be less receptive to the spread of Islam along trade routes. To explore this prediction, in Columns 3 and 4 of Table 3B , we focus on ethnic groups outside Muslim empires, further distinguishing between regions that were already monotheistic by 1050 CE as classified by O’Brien (1999) . Column 3 shows that limiting the sample to polytheistic areas during the diffusion of Islam, distance to trade routes is more precisely estimated. On the contrary, in Column 4 among the 172 groups where Christianity and Judaism were present by 1050 CE, proximity to trade routes negatively impacts Muslim representation suggesting that regions where monotheism was already in place found adherence to the Islamic institutional complex and access to the Muslim trade networks less beneficial.

The findings in Table 3B also raise the question whether the link between trade and religious adherence is particular to Islam. We tackle this issue by asking whether the identified relationship between Muslim representation and distance to trade routes systematically holds for other major religions. To facilitate comparisons in Column 1 of Table 4 , we replicate Column 5 of Table 3A where the dependent variable is the fraction of Muslims. In Columns 2, 3, and 4, we use as a dependent variable the percentage of people within an ethnic group adhering to three other major religions i.e., Christianity, Hinduism, and Buddhism, respectively. Lastly in Column 5, we use the fraction of the population adhering to local animistic, or shamanistic religions, known as Ethnoreligionists. The spatial distribution of these other religions does not seem to be influenced by the ancient trade routes. If anything Christians seem to be located further away from the pre-Islamic routes, a pattern mainly driven by groups in Asia and Africa.

Table 4 reports OLS estimates associating the share of different religions with geographical variables. Observations are at the level of ethnic group, the sample is the Old World (Europe, Asia and Africa). In all specifications the dependent variable is the share of the population belonging to a given religion in 2005 measured at ethnic group level from the World Religion Database. All columns include a set of country fixed effects.

These findings highlight the, until now, neglected crucial role of trade in shaping the differential adherence to Islam across ethnic groups and shed new light on the geographical origins and spatial distribution of Muslims within modern-day countries.

Robustness Checks

In the Appendix , we offer a series of sensitivity checks for the main pattern established in Tables ​ Tables1 1 and ​ and3A. 3A . First, in Columns 1 and 4 of Appendix Table 3 , we replicate the specifications reported in Columns 5 of Tables ​ Tables1 1 and ​ and3A 3A with the difference being that we replace the dependent variable with a dummy equal to one for countries/groups where Muslims are the absolute majority. The estimated coefficients suggest that a 1, 000-kilometer increase in the distance to pre-Islamic trade routes decreases the probability of finding a country (group within a country) with a Muslim majority by 16% (12%). Second, in Columns 2 and 5, we explore the non-linearity of proximity to pre-Islamic trade routes to capture the plausibly diminishing role of distance for regions further away from the trade hubs. The quadratic term on distance to pre-600 CE trade routes alternates in sign across levels of aggregation and is highly insignificant. This can be rationalized in different ways. First, this pattern may reflect the fact that despite our efforts to collect a comprehensive set of indicators regarding the presence of pre-Islamic regional trade opportunities (manifested in routes, roads, and ports) we are fully aware that measurement error in the mapping of ancient routes is non-trivial.

Second, an alternative interpretation of the non-significance of the quadratic term is that Muslims starting from the pre-600 CE trade network and continuing over the next 1, 000 years until the beginning of the European colonialism significantly expanded trade routes, adding myriad new connections and reaching vast areas in Sub-Saharan Africa and Asia. This implies that the network relevant for discerning a diminishing role of the proximity to trade routes on the spread of Islam is not the pre-600 CE one but the routes on the eve of the colonial era. To explore the empirical validity of this conjecture, we expanded our trade-routes dataset with information up to 1800 CE. Columns 3 and 6 of Appendix Table 3 clearly show that Muslim representation both across countries and across-groups within countries has a concave relationship with proximity to trade. Further increasing distance to pre-industrial trade hubs for regions already far from them has little bearing on their Muslim adherence. A note of caution is in order. Using data on trade routes after 600 CE implies that the empirical relationship cannot be unequivocally interpreted as it clearly reflects a two-way interplay from initial trade routes to the spread of Islam and from the latter to the further development of the trade network.

4. Mechanisms

So far, we have established a strong positive association between proximity to ancient trade routes and contemporary Muslim adherence and a positive link between geographically unequal regions and the presence of Muslim communities. In this section, we do two things. First, we investigate whether a group’s proximity to trade routes predicts its reliance on trade. Second, we open the black box of what inequality in land quality reflects, using contemporary data on land use and historical data on the subsistence pattern across groups.

Historical Trade Routes and Historical Dependence on Trade

Is it the case that groups closer to trade routes are more likely to engage in trade? Historical data on dependence on trade are notoriously difficult to come by. To the best of our knowledge, the only dataset that records the extent of trade at the group level in the pre-industrial era is the Standard Cross Cultural Sample (SCCS), which reports detailed information for 186 historical societies worldwide. 13 The entry we are interested in is the share of the overall subsistence needs that comes from trade ( v 819). Across the 121 societies in the Old World we compute the distance from their centroids (reported in the SCCS) to the closest trade routes before 600 CE and in 1800 CE.

In Table 5 , we report the results. The coefficient estimate on distance to the pre-600 CE trade routes is negative but statistically insignificant. The absence of significance is easy to understand. All but four of the SCCS societies were recorded by ethnographers after 1750 CE, which implies that their effective exposure to trade was that of the trade network as of 1800 and not the one of 600 CE. Indeed, when we replace the distance to 600 CE trade routes with the one of 1800 CE, a strong negative relationship emerges. Groups closer to the 1800 CE trade network consistently derive a larger share of subsistence from trade. Examples include the Javanese in Indonesia and the Rwala Bedouin, a large Arab tribe of northern Arabia and the Syrian Desert. Both groups are a mere 70 kilometers away from the trade routes and ports in 1800 CE and derived as much as 25% of their subsistence from trade. In Column 3, we drop the four SCCS societies that were documented by ethnographers before 1750, namely the Babylonians, the Hebrews, the Khmer, and the Romans, finding a similar pattern.

What Does Land Inequality Capture?

Our motivation for constructing the inequality in the distribution of agricultural potential across regions is that this statistic reflects the ecological conditions of the Arabian peninsula, the birthplace of Islam. Indeed, across the 36, 582 land quality observations in the Old World among the 1, 285 cells that belong to the Arabian Peninsula, the Gini coefficient of land quality is 0.87 with an average land quality of 0.03 whereas the statistics for the rest of the regions are 0.57 and 0.32, respectively. 14 In a stage of development when land quality dictates the productive structure of the economy, one would expect societies along unequally endowed territories to have a specific productive structure with herding dominating the arid and semi-arid regions and farming taking place in the few fertile ones. This was certainly the economic landscape of the pre-industrial Arabian peninsula. Below, we verify this link using historical and contemporary data across groups on the dependence on pastoralism and agriculture.

The data on land use come from Ramankutty et al. (2008) and provide at the grid level of 0.083 by 0.083 decimal degrees estimates on the share of land allocated to pasture and agriculture in 2000. We aggregate this information at the homeland level to obtain a measure of how tilted land allocation is towards pasture. The data on the historical traits across groups come from Murdock (1967) who produced an Ethnographic Atlas (published in twenty-nine installments in the anthropological journal Ethnology) that coded around 60 variables, capturing cultural, societal, and economic characteristics of 1, 270 ethnicities around the world. We linked Murdock’s Ethnographic Atlas groups to the Ethnologue’s linguistic homelands in the Old World. These two datasets do not always use the same name to identify a group. Utilizing several sources and the updated version of Murdock’s Atlas produced by Gray (1999) , we were able to identify the pre-colonial traits as recorded in the Ethnographic Atlas for 1, 210 linguistic homelands in the Ethnologue (2005) . 15

In the first three columns of Table 6 , the dependent variable is the log ratio of pastoral over agricultural area in 2000 across linguistic homelands. 16 All columns include country-specific constants. Within countries, groups residing along poor and unequally endowed regions display a larger land allocation towards animal husbandry compared to farming. Adding in Column 2 the geographic variables discussed above does not change the pattern. The only additional finding is that groups located in rugged regions are also more dependent on pastoralism than agriculture. In Column 3, we verify that Muslim groups today live in homelands that display this particular type of land use, i.e., a land allocation skewed against agriculture and in favor of pastoral activities.

Table 5 reports OLS estimates associating the relative importance of trade with distance to trade routes. Observations are at the level of a historical society, the sample is the Old World (Europe, Asia and Africa). In all specifications the dependent variable is the (log of 1 plus) share from trade in subsistence measured as reported in the Standard Cross Cultural Sample (SCCS). Column (3) excludes societies that were documented by ethnographers before 1750 (Babylonians, Hebrews, Khmer, and Romans).

Is it the case that groups residing in habitats where farming today is limited and herding significantly more common had a similar lopsided type of subsistence in the pre-industrial era? This is what we ask in Column 4 where the dependent variable is the log ratio of the share of subsistence derived from animal husbandry over agriculture as recorded in the Ethnographic Atlas. Groups that today allocate more of their land towards pastoralism also used to derive more of their livelihood from similar activities in the past, suggesting the persistence in the structure of production across groups.

In Columns 5 to 7, we replicate the pattern shown in Columns 1 to 3 with the difference being that on the left hand side of the equation, instead of the contemporary land allocation, we use the log ratio of the historical subsistence share from animal husbandry relative to agriculture. Groups residing in homelands of limited potential for agriculture dotted with few pockets of fertile land also used to obtain more from herding and less from agricultural products in the pre-colonial era. Adding the geographical covariates in Column 6 reveals that the presence of desert and of regions with irrigation potential also skew subsistence towards animal husbandry. Finally, in Column 7, we show that indeed Muslim groups are those that historically were more dependent on pastoralism and less on farming, corroborating one of the long-standing themes in the environmental history of Islamic Eurasia and North Africa, namely, the interface between the steppe and the sown ( Mikhail, 2012 ).

In this environment where each area specializes in its comparative advantage (farmers on the fertile pockets and herders on the relatively arid ones), a larger geographical Gini coefficient may correspond to larger potential gains from trade. Richerson (1996) , for example, observes that “despite the emphasis on animals, most herders are dependent on crop staples for part of their caloric intake … procured by client agricultural families that are often part of the society and the presence of specialized tradesmen that organize the exchange of agricultural products for animal products.” This suggests that an exchange economy may be more vibrant within a community of many herders and few farmers. To shed light on this conjecture, we rely on the Standard Cross Cultural Sample (SCCS). Specifically, in Column 8 of Table 6 , we ask whether societies relying more on pastoralism relative to agriculture also derive more of their subsistence needs from trade; across the 186 ethnographic societies worldwide, this is indeed the case. Overall, the results in Table 6 reveal how the specific geographic endowments of Muslim homelands give rise to a distinct specialization pattern: a pastoral economy with few farmers where trade is important.

Why Ecological Similarity to the Arabian Peninsula Matters for the Spread of Islam

At first blush, showing that Muslim regions are ecologically similar to the birthplace of Islam, i.e., the Arabian peninsula, is consistent with various interpretations.

First, Michalopoulos (2012) argues that cultural groups have location-specific human capital derived from the type of geography they inhabit. Hence, when members of such groups leave their group’s homeland they are likely to target regions that are productively similar to their ancestral territories to ensure transferability of their skills. For example, early farmers and pastoralists moving out of the Fertile Crescent on the eve of the Neolithic Revolution follow this pattern of dispersal, i.e., farmers moving to land suitable for agriculture and herders targeting landscapes appropriate for animal husbandry. One may apply a similar reasoning to the diffusion of Islam. Since the productive toolset of early Muslims was fine-tuned to the arid landscapes of the Arabian Peninsula, seeing Muslims migrating to lands similar to their ancestral regions can be easily rationalized.

Second, Bulliet (1975) convincingly argues that one crucial element for understanding the spread of Muslim empires is the use of the camel that provided the Arab armies a military edge over their rivals. So, terrains suitable for deploying the camel would be more easily conquered whereas others would remain beyond the reach of Muslim rulers. Chaney (2012) shows empirically how a desert ecosystem is indeed predictive of the Arab conquests and Muslim adherence across countries today.

Both of these arguments are very relevant for understanding the spread of Islam in places that experienced either a Muslim conqueror and/or a significant influx of Muslims. Nevertheless, in many of the cases discussed in the historical section, Islam was often voluntarily adopted by the local rulers in absence of significant Muslim population movements. What arguments may then rationalize the voluntary adoption of Islam across geographically unequal regions? Below we offer some tentative explanations.

Islam, Trade, and Unequal Geography

We offer two complementary accounts that high-light the pro-trade stance of Islam. The first derives from the observation that historically within geographically unequal societies trade is likely to play an important role for subsistence (see Column 8 of Table 6 ). Hence, to the extent that Islam offered an institutional framework promoting exchange, groups across geographically unequal territories would have an added incentive to convert. Several Islamicists have stressed the pro-trade elements of the Muslim institutional complex. According to Cohen (1971) , “[Islam is a] blue-print of a politico-economic organization which has overcome the many basic technical problems of trade.” Trade called for new types of economic organization that required stronger authority ( Davidson, 1969 ). An important advantage of Islam with respect to previous arrangements was the fact that it offered a powerful ideology with built-in sanctions that created non-material interest in holding to the terms of contracts ( Ensminger, 1997 ). This common platform allegedly generated trust and contributed to the reduction in transaction costs while doing business with fellow Muslims.

Second, in our companion paper, Michalopoulos, Naghavi, and Prarolo (2016) , we advance theoretically a related hypothesis where the Islamic economic rules arise to mitigate social tensions across Arabia’s tribes exposed to long-distance trade opportunities during the 7th century CE. In a nutshell, we argue that trade diversion over Arabia created new potential economic benefits for the scattered oases by transforming them to trade hubs providing services to the trading community ( Watt, 1961 ). Caravans, however, for thousands of miles were constantly exposed to raids by the Bedouins, who made up a considerable fraction of the population at that time ( Berkey, 2003 ). In this historical backdrop, we hypothesize that Islamic rules were devised in response to the costly nature of predation between the Bedouins and oasis dwellers, offering a framework whose redistributive principies safeguarded exchange over numerous and heterogeneous tribal territories ( Bogle, 1998 ). 17

This view of Islam as an institutional package engineered to allow the flourishing of long-distance trade across unequally endowed regions generates an auxiliary prediction: Islam should be able to gain a hearing more readily across unequal territories close to trade routes. Empirically, this can be tested by adding the interaction between distance to trade routes and ports and the degree of geographic inequality. Columns 1 and 2 of Table 7 are country-level regressions and Columns 3 and 4 focus on ethnic groups within countries. Across both units of aggregation the interaction term enters with a negative sign and it is statistically significant. 18 The point estimates in Specification 1 suggest that the effect of land inequality on Muslim adherence across countries becomes insignificant for countries farther than 650 kilometers from the trade routes as of 600 CE, pointing to the differential incentives to convert to Islam among geographically unequal regions in the vicinity of historical trade routes.

Table 7 reports OLS estimates associating the share of Muslims with geographical variables. Observations are at the level of countries (columns 1 and 2) or ethnic groups (columns 3 and 4). The sample is the Old World (Europe, Asia and Africa). In columns 1 and 2 the dependent variable is the share of Muslims in 1900 across countries from McCleary and Barro (2005), while in columns 3 and 4 the dependent variable is the share of Muslims across ethnic groups from the World Religion Database (WRD). Controls are Distance to Mecca, Distance to the Coast, Absolute Latitude, Ln Average Land Quality, Ln Land Area, Ln Ruggedness, Irrigation Potential Indicator and Presence of Desert Indicator.

The Supplementary Appendix gives detailed definitions, data sources and summary statistics for all variables. Columns 1 and 2 (3 and 4) include a set of continental (country) fixed effects. Standard errors, in parentheses, are robust to heteroscedasticity (columns 1 and 2) and clustered at the country level (columns 3 and 4). ***, **, and * indicate statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

Although the decline in the predictive power of inequality in agricultural endowments farther from trade routes is consistent with the proposed view that Islamic rules were better suited for geographically unequal communities close to the trade network, it is far from a proof. To establish that converting to Islam indeed facilitated trade and changed the groups’ institutional framework – increasing redistribution and mitigating conflict – one would need data before and after Islamization. Cross-sectional variation only cannot shed light on whether converting to Islam changed the underlying institutional structure, or if groups that already had traits similar to what the Islamic scriptures prescribed found it easier to become Muslim. Taking these qualifiers into account in the Appendix we show that Muslim groups are different from non-Muslim ones in some of their institutional and societal arrangements. Specifically, in Appendix Table 4 we show that Muslim societies as recorded by ethnographers in the Old World are more likely to be politically centralized, harbor beliefs in moral gods, and follow equitable inheritance rules. Moreover, a strong link between an unequal geography and social stratification is present across non-Muslim groups but muted across Muslim ones.

5. Conclusion

In this study we examine the historical roots of Muslim adherence within as well as across countries. First, we digitize and combine a multitude of historical sources, to construct detailed proxies of ancient, pre-Islamic trade routes, harbors, and ports and show that regions in the vicinity of such locations are systematically more likely to be Muslim today. We view this finding as offering large-scale econometric support to a widely held conjecture among prominent Islamicists like Lapidus (2002) , Berkey (2003) , and Lewis (1993) , and complement this empirical regularity with historical accounts illustrating the importance of trade contacts in the process of Islamization of various prominent locations in Africa and Asia.

Second, we establish that Muslim communities tend to reside in habitats that are ecologically similar to those of the Arabian Peninsula, the birthplace of Islam. Specifically, we show that Muslim homelands are dominated by arid and semi-arid lands where animal husbandry is the norm, and dotted with few niches of fertile land where farming is feasible. Overall, a poor and unequal distribution of agricultural potential predicts Muslim adherence. We discuss the various mechanisms that may give rise to this phenomenon and offer evidence consistent with the view of Islam as an institutional package appropriate for societies residing along unequally endowed regions in the vicinity of trade opportunities.

The empirical analysis is conducted across countries and across ethnic groups within countries. Exploring within-country variation is crucial in our context given the intimate relationship between country formation and religious identity. Across both levels of aggregation, there is a robust link between proximity to pre-Islamic trade routes, geographic inequality, and Muslim representation. The identified pattern is unique to the Muslim denomination and it obtains for regions that historically have not been part of a Muslim empire. Overall, the empirical analysis highlights the prominent role of history in shaping the contemporary spatial distribution of Muslim societies.

We view these findings as a stepping stone for further research. For example, focusing on specific regions where historical data may be available, one may explore time variation in the speed at which Islam made inroads to the respective communities. Moreover, one element we do not touch upon is why religious beliefs – once adopted – persist over time. Insights from the rapidly growing theoretical and empirical literature on the persistence of beliefs and attitudes may shed light on this phenomenon (see Bisin and Verdier, 2000 ; and Voigtlander and Voth, 2012 ). Finally, having identified some of the forces behind the formation and spread of Islam, one might examine the economic and political consequences for the short-run and the long-run development of the Muslim world (see Michalopoulos, Naghavi, and Prarolo, 2016 ). We plan to address some of these issues in subsequent research.

Table 6 reports OLS estimates associating (contemporary and historical) measures of dependence on pastoralism and agriculture with land inequality, adherence to Islam and other historical and geographic variables. The dependent variable in columns 1 to 3 is the log ratio of pastoral to agricultural lands from Ramankutty et al., 2008. The log ratio of historical subsistence of pastoral to agricultural share, from Murdock’s Ethnographic Atlas is the dependent variable in columns 4 to 7 and the (log +1) share of subsistence from trade from the SCCS dataset in column 8. Observations are at the ethnic group level in columns 1 to 7 and at the level of historical societies in column 8. The sample used is the Old-World part of the Ethnologue (columns 1 to 3), its intersection with the Murdock’s Ethnographic Atlas (columns 4 to 7) and all groups in the Standard Cross Cultural Sample in column 8.

The Supplementary Appendix gives detailed definitions, data sources and summary statistics for all variables. Columns 1 to 7 include a set of country fixed effects with errors clustered at the country level in parentheses, while those of column 8 are robust to heteroscedasticity. ***, **, and * indicate statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

Supplementary Material

Appendix table 1 -.

Appendix Table 1, Panel A, reports summary statistics for the main variables employed in the empirical analysis at the county level. Panel B gives the correlation structure of these variables.

The Supplementary Appendix gives detailed variable definitions and data sources.

Appendix Table 2 -

Appendix Table 2, Panel A, reports summary statistics for the main variables employed in the empirical analysis at the ethnic group level. Panel B gives the correlation structure of these variables.

Appendix Table 3 -

Appendix Table 3 reports OLS estimates associating measures of Muslim adherence with geographical variables. Observations are at the level of countries (columns 1 to 3) or ethnic group (columns 4 to 6), the sample is the Old World (Europe, Asia and Africa). In column 1 (4) the dependent variable is a dummy equal to one if the share of Muslim in the country (ethnic group) in 1900 (2005) is greater than 50%, from McCleary and Barro (2005) (World Religion Database). In columns 2 and 3 the dependent variable is the share of Muslim population in 1900 measured at country level, while in columns 5 and 6 the dependent variable is the share of Muslim population in 2005 at the ethnic group level. Included controls are Distance to Mecca, Distance to the Coast, Absolute Latitude, Ln Average Land Quality, Ln Land Area, Ln Ruggedness, an Irrigation Potential Indicator and the Presence of Desert Indicator.

The Supplementary Appendix gives detailed variable definitions, data sources and summary statistics for all variables. Columns 1 to 3 (4 to 6) include a set of continental (country) fixed effects. Standard errors, in parentheses, are robust to heteroscedasticity (columns 1 to 3) and clustered at the country level (columns 4 to 6). ***, **, and * indicate statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

Appendix Table 4 -

Appendix Table 4 reports OLS estimates associating Muslim adherence across groups to various societal traits and geographical variables. In column 1 the dependent variable is the degree of jurisdictional hierarchy beyond the local community level. In column 2 the dependent variable is a dummy reflecting whether the local gods are supportive of human morality. In columns 3 to 5 the dependent variable is an indicator whether a group is socially stratified and in columns 6 and 7 the dependent variable reflects whether there is egalitarian inheritance with respect to movable and land property, respectively. In column 4 (5) the sample is restricted to ethnic groups with a share of Muslim population above 95% (below 10%). Observations are at the ethnicity level and the sample comprises of groups in the Old World for which we have created a correspondence between the Ethnologue and the Murdock’s Ethnographic Atlas. Controls are Absolute Latitude, Ln Average Land Quality, Ln Land Area, Ln Ruggedness, an Irrigation Potential Indicator and Presence of Desert Indicator.

The Supplementary Appendix gives detailed variable definitions, data sources and summary statistics for all variables. Standard errors in parentheses are clustered at the country level. ***, **, and * indicate statistical significance at the 1%, 5%, and 10% level, respectively.

1 Traslation by Dr. Muhammad Taqi-ud-Din Al-Hilali and Dr. Muhammad Muhsin Khan in 1999.

2 See Barro and McCleary (2006a , 2006b ) for an overview and Barro and McCleary (2003) , La Porta et al. (1997) , Martin, Doppelhofer, and Miller (2004) , and Pryor (2007) , among others for mixed evidence of the impact of religion on economic indicators.

3 All distance measures are constructed in the following manner. We generate a grid of 0.5 by 0.5 decimal degrees and intersect the resulting cells with the country and homeland boundaries. We then calculate the distance from the centroid of each cell within the country/homeland to the nearest feature. To arrive at a single distance term for each unit of aggregation, we take the mean value of the distances across the cells that fall within the country/ethnic homeland borders. This procedure is more accurate than using only the country’ or homeland’s centroid. Moreover, using the minimum or the maximum distance instead of the mean distance to the attributes of interest delivers noisier coefficients.

4 WRD classifies as Muslims the followers of Islam in its two main branches (with schools of law, rites or sects): Sunnis or Sunnites (Hanafite, Hanbalite, Malikite, Shafiite) and Shias or Shiites (Ithna Ashari, Ismaili, Alawite, and Zaydi); also Kharijite and other orthodox sects; reform movements (Wahhabi, Sanusi, Mahdiya); also heterodox sects (Ahmadiya, Druzes, Yazidis); but excludes syncretistic religions with Muslim elements and partially Islamized tribal religionists.

5 Hsu et al. (2008) show that the country level estimates for Muslim representation in WRD are highly correlated (above 0.97) with similar statistics available from World Values Survey, Pew Global Assessment Project, CIA World Factbook, and the U.S. Department of State. At the ethnic group level, there are no comparable statistics.

6 For some language groups in WLMS (2006) the WRD offers information at the subgroup level. In this case the religious affiliation is the average across the subgroups.

7 In the online Appendix , we discuss in detail the components of the land quality index and present the sources of the data used in the empirical analysis.

8 We focus on countries with at least three regional observations of land quality to ensure that our findings are not driven by countries with limited regional coverage. Using the Muslim representation in 2000 as the dependent variable, the coefficients of interest are larger and more precisely estimated. Presumably this is because earlier estimates of religious affiliation are noisier.

9 We follow Bentzen, Kaarsen, and Wingender (2016) and define the irrigation potential of an area as land that is classified in irrigation Impact Class 5. Impact Class 5 are those cells where irrigation can more than double agricultural yields. Out of the 127 countries, 72% have some irrigation potential whereas 28% of countries feature no such cells.

10 We follow Hsiang (2013) to visually display the uncertainty of the regression estimates in Figures ​ Figures3 3 and ​ and4 4 .

11 Similar to the cross-country regressions, we focus on ethnic groups with at least three regional land quality observations. Using all ethnic groups irrespective of the underlying geographic coverage does not change the results.

12 The results presented here are OLS estimates with the standard errors clustered at the country level. Adjusting for spatial autocorrelation following Conley (1999) delivers more conservative standard errors.

13 The SCCS comprises ethnographically well-documented societies, selected by George P. Murdock and Douglas R. White, published in the journal Ethnology in 1969, and followed by several publications that coded the SCCS societies for many different types of societal characteristics.

14 The Arabian Peninsula consists of the following 9 contemporary countries: Yemen, Oman, Iraq, Jordan, Qatar, Bahrain, Kuwait, Saudi Arabia, and the United Arab Emirates.

15 Unlike the SCCS dataset, Murdock’s Ethnographie Atlas does not have information on trade-related traits.

16 Note that the number of groups in Columns 1 to 3 is 2, 845 instead of the 3,181 covered in Table 3 . This is because for 336 linguistic homelands the allocation of land either towards farming or towards pasture in 2000 is 0 so the log of their ratio is not well defined.

17 The link between the structure of production, institutional formation and religion can be readily glimpsed in the works of Ibn Khaldun (1377) and Marx (1833 [1970]) . Ibn Khaldun (1377) notes that “it is the physical environment-habitat, climate, soil, and food, that explain the different ways in which people, nomadic or sedentary, satisfy their needs, and form their customs and institutions,” whereas Marx (1833 [1970]) highlights that religion, like any other social institution, is a by-product of the society’s productive forces.

18 Note that when we use the trade network before 1800 CE the direct effect of distance to trade routes also reflects reverse causality. Nevertheless, irrespective of who set up the routes, we may still explore whether it is unequally endowed regions that are differentially impacted.

* We would like to thank the Editor and three anonymous referees for their valuable comments. We have also benefited from discussions with several colleagues and comments from numerous seminars and conferences.

  • Acemoglu D, Johnson S, and Robinson JA (2001): “ The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation ,” American Economie Review , 91 ( 5 ), 1369–1401. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Acemoglu D, Johnson S, and Robinson JA (2002): “ Reversal Of Fortune: Geography And Institutions in the Making of the Modern World Income Distribution ,” Quarterly Journal of Economies , 107 ( 4 ), 1231–1294. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Andaya B, and Andaya L (1982): A History of Malaysia . Macmillan, London. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Barrett DB, Kurian GT, and Johnson TM (2001): World Christian Encyclopedia , 2nd Edition. Oxford University Press, Oxford. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Barro R, and Mccleary RM (2003): “ Religion and Economie Growth Across Countries ,” American Sociological Review , 68 ( 5 ), 760–781. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Barro R, and Mccleary RM (2006a): “ Religion and Economy ,” Journal of Economic Perspectives , 20 ( 2 ), 49–72. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Barro R, and Mccleary RM (2006b): “ Religion and Political Economy in an International Panel ,” Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion , 45 ( 2 ), 149–175. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Becker SO, and Woessmann DL (2009): “ Was Weber Wrong? A Human Capital Theory of Protestant Economic History ,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics , 124 ( 2 ), 531–596. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Benabou R, and Tirole J (2001): “ Willpower and Personal Rules ,” Journal of Political Economy , 112 ( 4 ), 848–886. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Bentzen JS, Kaarsen N, and Wlngender AM (2016): “ Irrigation and Autocracy ,” Journal of the European Economic Association , forthcoming. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Berkey JP (2003): The Formation of Islam: Religion and Society in the Near East, 600–1800 . Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Bisin A, and Verdier T (2000): “ Beyond the Melting Pot: Cultural Transmission, Marriage, and the Evolution of Ethnic and Religious Traits ,” Quarterly Journal of Economics , 115 , 955–988. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Blydes L (2014): “ How Does Islamist Local Governance Affect the Lives of Women? ,” Governance , 27 ( 3 ), 489–509. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Boahen A, Ajayi J, and Tldy M (1966): Topics in West African History . Longman, London. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Bogle EC (1998): Islam: Origin and Belief . University of Texas Press, Austin, TX. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Botticini M, and Eckstein Z (2005): “ Jewish Occupational Selection: Education, Restrictions, or Minorities? ,” Journal of Economic History , 65 , 922–948. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Botticini M, and Eckstein Z (2007): “ From Farmers to Merchants, Conversions and Diaspora: Human Capital and Jewish History ,” Journal of the European Economic Association , 5 , 885–926. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Brice WC, and Kennedy H (2001): An Historical Atlas of Islam . Brill Academic Publishers, Leiden. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Bulllet RW (1975): The Camel and the Wheel . Columbia University Press, New York, NY. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Bulllet RW (1979): Conversion to Islam in the Medieval Period: An Essay in Quantitative History. Harvard University Press , Cambridge, MA. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Campante F, and Yanagizawa-Drott D (2015): “ Does Religion Affect Economic Growth and Happiness? Evidence from Ramadan ,” Quarterly Journal of Economics , 130 ( 2 ), 615–658. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Cantoni Б (2012): “ Adopting a New Religion: The Case of Protestantism in 16th Century Germany ,” Economie Journal , 122 ( 560 ), 502–531. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Ceryellati M, and Sunde U (2017): “On the Emergence of Religious Norms – Theory and Evidence from the Protestant Reformation,” Working Paper , mimeo University of Bologna. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Chaney E (2012): “Islam and Human Capital Formation: Evidence from Pre-Modern Muslim Science,” in Handbook of the Economies of Religion , ed. by McCleary R Oxford University Press, Oxford. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Chaney E (2016): “Religion and the Rise and Fall of Islamic Science,” Working Paper , mimeo Harvard University. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Chaney E, and Hornbeck R (2016): “ Economic Dynamics in the Malthusian Era: Evidence from the 1609 Spanish Expulsion of the Moriscos ,” Economic Journal , 126 ( 594 ), 1404–1440. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Chaudhuri K (1985): Trade and Civilisation in the Indian Ocean: An Economic History from the Rise of Islam to 1750 . Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Cllnglngsmith O, Khwaja AI, and Kremer M (2009): “ Estimating the Impact of The Hajj: Religion and Tolerance in Islam’s Global Gathering ,” Quarterly Journal of Economics , 124 ( 3 ), 1133–1170. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Cohen A (1971): “Cultural Strategies in the Organization of Trading Diasporas,” in The Development of Indigenous Trade and Markets in West Africa , ed. by Meillassoux C, pp. 206–281. Oxford University Press, London. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Conley TG (1999): “ GMM Estimation with Cross Sectional Dependence ,” Journal of Econometrics , 92 ( 1 ), 1–45. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Davidson B (1969): A History of East and Central Africa . Doubleday Anchor Books, New York, NY. [ Google Scholar ]
  • de Graauw A, Malone-Downlng B, and McCormick M (2014): “Geodatabase of Ancient Ports and Harbours,” DARMC Scholarly Data Series, Data Contribution Series 2013–2. (version 1.1) . DARMC, Center for Geographic Analysis, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Devisse J (1988): “Trade and trade routes in West Africa,” in General history of Africa 3: Africa from the seventh to the eleventh century , ed. by Elfasi M, and H. I., pp. 367–435. Heinemann, London. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Eaton R. μ. (1996): The Rise of Islam and the Bengal Frontier, 1204–1760 . University of California Press, Berkeley, CA. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Elliot H, and Dowson J (1867): The History of India: As Told by Its Own Historians. The Muhammadan Period, v.1 . Trübner and Company, London. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Engerman SL, and Sokoloff KL (1997): “Factor Endowments, Institutions, and Differential Paths of Growth among New World Economies,” in How Latin America Fell Behind , ed. by Haber S, pp. 260–304. Stanford University Press, Stanford, CA. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Engerman SL, and Sokoloff KL (2002): “Factor Endowments, Inequality, and Paths of Development among New World Economies,” Working Paper No. 9259, NBER. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Ensminger J (1997): “ Transaction Costs and Islam: Explaining Conversion in Africa ,” Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics , 153 ( 1 ), 3–29. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Esposito J (1999): The Oxford History of Islam . Oxford University Press, Oxford. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Ethnologue (2005): Languages of the World , SIL International; Fifteenth edition. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Foltz R (1999): Religions of the Silk Road: Overland Trade and Cultural Exchange from Antiquity to the Fifteenth Century . St. Martin’ Press, New York, NY. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Geertz C (1968): Islam Observed: Religious Development in Morocco and Indonesia . University of Chicago Press, Chicago. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Gennaioli N, and Rainer I (2007): “ The Modern Impact of Precolonial Centralization in Africa ,” Journal of Economic Growth , 12 ( 3 ), 185–234. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Gray PJ (1999): “ A Corrected Ethnographic Atlas ,” Wolrd Cultures , 10 , 24–85. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Greif A (1994): “ Cultural Beliefs and the Organization of Society: A History and Theoretical Reflection on Collectivist and Individualist Societies ,” The Journal of Politica! Economy , 102 ( 5 ), 912–950. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Greif A, and Tabellini G (2010): “ Cultural and Institutional Bifurcation: China and Europe Compared ,” American Economic Review: Papers and Proceedings , 100 ( 2 ), 135–140. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Guiso L, Sapienza P, and Zlngales L (2003): “ People’s Opium? Religion and Economic Attitudes ,” Journal of Monetary Economics , 50 ( 1 ), 225–282. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Guiso L, Sapienza P, and Zlngales L (2016): “ Long Term Persistence ,” Journal of the European Economic Association , 14 ( 6 ), 1401–1436. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Hiskett M (1984): The Development of Islam in West Africa . Longman, London. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Holt P, Lambton A, and Lewis B (1970): The Cambridge History of Islam, v. 2A . Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Houben VJ (2003): “ Southeast Asia and Islam ,” The Annals of the American Academy of Politicai and Social Science , 588 ( 1 ), 149–170. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Hsiang SM (2013): “ Visually-Weighted Regression ,” Working Paper, mimeo Princeton University . [ Google Scholar ]
  • Hsu B, Glbbon J, Hackett C, and Reynolds A (2008): “ Estimating the Religious Composition of All Nations: An Empirical Assessment of the World Christian Database ,” Journal for the Scientific Study of Religion , 74 ( 4 ), 678–693. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Khaldun Ibn (1377): Muqaddimah: An Introduction to History, transl . Rosenthal Franz (1967). Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Ibrahim M (1990): Merchant Capital and Islam . University of Texas Press, Austin. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Insoll T (2003): The Archaeology of Islam in Sub-Saharan Africa . Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Iyigun M (2010): “Monotheism (From a Sociopolitical and Economic Perspective),” Working Paper , mimeo University of Colorado. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Jha S (2013): “ Trade, Institutions and Ethnic Tolerance: Evidence from South Asia ,” American Political Science Review , 107 ( 4 ), 806–832. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Kuran T (2003): “ The Islamic Commercial Crisis: Institutional Roots of Economic Underdevel-opment in the Middle East ,” Journal of Economic History , 63 , 414–446. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Kuran T (2004): “ Why the Middle East Is Economically Underdeveloped: Historical Mechanisms of Institutional Stagnation ,” Journal of Economic Perspectives , 18 , 71–90. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Kuran T, and S. Lustig (2012): “ Judicial Biases in Ottoman Istanbul: Islamic Justice and Its Compatibility with Modern Economic Life ,” Journal of Law and Economics , 55 ( 3 ), 631–666. [ Google Scholar ]
  • La Porta R, Lopez-De-Sllanes F, Shleifer A, and Vlshny R (1997): “ Legal Determinants of External Finance ,” Journal of Finance , 52 ( 3 ), 1131–1150. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Lapidus IM (2002): A History of Islamic Societies . Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Last M (1979): “Some Economic Aspects of Conversion in Hausaland (Nigeria),” in Conversion to Islam , ed. by Levtzion N, pp. 236–246. Holmes and Meier, New York, NY. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Levtzion N (1979): Conversion to Islam . Holmes and Meier Publishers, New York, NY. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Levtzion N, and Pouwels R (2000): History Of Islam In Africa . Ohio University Press, Athens, OH. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Lewis B (1993): The Arabs in History , 6th Edition. Oxford University Press, Oxford. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Lewis IM (1980): Islam in Tropical Africa . International African Institute, London. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Makhdum SZ (2006): Tuhfat al-Mujahidin: A Historical Epic ofthe Sixteenth Century. Translated from Arabic by S. Muhammad Husayn Nainar . Islamic Book Trust, KualaLumpur / Calicut. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Martin XSI, Doppelhofer G, and Miller RI (2004): “Determinants of Long-Run Growth: a Bayesian Averaging of Classical Estimates (BACE) Approach ,” American Economic Review , 94 ( 4 ), 813–835. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Marx K (1833 [1970]): Critique of Hegel’s Philosophy of Right, Edited by Joseph O’Malley . Cambridge University Press, Cambrdige. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Mattulada (1983): ““Islam di Sulawesi Selatan” (Islam in South Sulawesi),” in Agama dan Perubahan Sosial (Religion and Social Change) , ed. by Abdullah T Rajawali, Jakarta. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Mccormick M, Huang G, Zambottl G, and Lavash J (2013): “Roman Road Network (version 2008),” DARMC Scholarly Data Series, Data Contribution Series 2013–5 . DARMC, Center for Geographic Analysis, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Meri J, and Bacharach J (2006): Medieval Islamic Civilization: An Encyclopedia, Routledge Encyclopedias of the Middle Ages . Routledge, New York. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Michalopoulos S (2012): “ The Origins of Ethnolinguistic Diversity ,” American Economic Review , 102 ( 4 ), 1508–1539. [ PMC free article ] [ PubMed ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Michalopoulos S, Naghavi A, and Prarolo G (2016): “ Islam, Inequality, and Pre-Industrial Comparative Development ,” Journal of Development Economics , 120 , 86–98. [ PMC free article ] [ PubMed ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Michalopoulos S, and Papaioannou E (2013): “ Pre-Colonial Ethnic Institutions and Contemporary African Development ,” Econometrica , 81 ( 1 ), 113–152. [ PMC free article ] [ PubMed ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Mlkhall A (2012): Water on Sand . Oxford University Press, Oxford. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Miller J (1969): The spice trade of the Roman Empire, 29 B.C. to A.D. 641, Oxford University Press Academic Monogra Series . Clarendon Press, Oxford. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Minahan J (2014): Ethnic Groups of North, East, and Central Asia: An Encyclopedia, Ethnic groups of the world . Abc-Clio Incorporated, Santa Barbara, CA. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Nunn N, and Puga D (2012): “ Ruggedness: The Blessing of Bad Geography in Africa ,” Review of Economics and Statistics , 94 ( 1 ), 20–36. [ Google Scholar ]
  • O’Brien PK (1999): Oxford Atlas of World History . Oxford University Press, New York, NY. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Peoples HC, and Marlowe FW (2012): “ Subsistence and the Evolution of Religion ,” Human Nature , 23 ( 3 ), 253–269. [ PubMed ] [ Google Scholar ]
  • Platteau J-P (2008): “ Religion, Politics, and Development: Lessons from the Lands of Islam ,” Journal of Economie Behavior and Organization , 68 , 329–351. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Platteau J-P (2011): “ Political Instrumentalization of Islam and Threat of an Obscurantist Deadlock ,” World Development , 39 , 243–260. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Pryor FB (2007): “ The Economic Impact of Islam on Developing Countries ,” World Development , 35 ( 11 ), 1815–1835. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Ramankutty N, Foley JA, Monfreda с., and Foley J (2008): “ Farming the Planet: 1. Geographic Distribution of Global Agricultural Lands in the Year 2000 ,” Global Biogeochemical Cycles , 22 , 1–19. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Ramankutty N, Foley JA, Norman J, and McSweeney K (2002): “ The Global Distribution of Cultivable Lands: Current Patterns and Sensitivity to Possible Climate Change ,” Global Ecology and Biogeography , 11 , 377–392. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Rawlinson H (2003): Ancient and Medieval History of India . Bharatiya Kala Prakashan, New Delhi. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Richerson PJ (1996): Principles of Human Ecology . Pearson Custom Pub, New York, NY. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Ricklefs M (1991): A History of Modern Indonesia since c.1300 , 2nd Edition. MacMillan, London. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Robinson D (2004): Muslim Societies in African History, New Approaches to African History . Cambridge University Press, New York, NY. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Roemer HR (2000): History of the Turkic Peoples in the Pre-Islamic Period . Klaus Schwarz Verlag, Berlin. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Roes FL, and Raymond M (2003): “ Belief in Moralizing Gods ,” Evolution and Human Behavior , 24 , 126–135. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Rubin J (2009): “ Social Insurance, Commitment, and the Origin of Law: Interest Bans in Early Christianity ,” Journal of Law and Economics , 52 , 761–777. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Shillington K (2005): Encyclopedia of African history, v. 3 . Fitzroy Dearborn, New York, NY. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Sinor D (1990): The Cambridge History of Early Inner Asia, v. 1 . Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Soucek S (2000): A History of Inner Asia . Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Trimingham JS (1962): A History of Islam in West Africa . Oxford University Press, London. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Trimingham JS (1964): Islam in east Africa . Clarendon Press, Oxford. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Voigtlander N, and Voth H-J (2012): “ Persecution Perpetuated: The Medieval Origins of Anti-Semitic Violence in Nazi Germany ,” Quarterly Journal of Economics , 127 , 1339–1392. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Wade G (2009): “ An Early Age of Commerce in Southeast Asia, 900–1300 CE ,” Journal of South-east Asian Studies , 40 ( 2 ), 221–265. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Watt W. μ. (1961): Muhammad: Prophet and Statesman . Oxford University Press, London. [ Google Scholar ]
  • Wink A (1990): Al-Hind: The Making of the Indo-Islamic World . E.J. Brill, Leiden. [ Google Scholar ]
  • WLMS (2006): World Language Mapping System, Version 3.2 Available on-line at http://www.gmi.org/wlms/ .
  • Wood E (2003): Empire of Capital . VERSO, New York, NY. [ Google Scholar ]
  • WRD (2006): World Religion Database , BRILL, Available on-line at http://www.worldreligiondatabase.org/ . [ Google Scholar ]

Stanford University

SPICE Logo

SPICE is a program of the Freeman Spogli Institute for International Studies.

The Spread of Islam in West Africa: Containment, Mixing, and Reform from the Eighth to the Twentieth Century

how did islam travel to africa

While the presence of Islam in West Africa dates back to eighth century, the spread of the faith in regions that are now the modern states of Senegal, Gambia, Guinea, Burkina Faso, Niger, Mali and Nigeria, was in actuality, a gradual and complex process. Much of what we know about the early history of West Africa comes from medieval accounts written by Arab and North African geographers and historians. Specialists have used several models to explain why Africans converted to Islam. Some emphasize economic motivations, others highlight the draw of Islam’s spiritual message, and a number stress the prestige and influence of Arabic literacy in facilitating state building. While the motivations of early conversions remain unclear, it is apparent that the early presence of Islam in West Africa was linked to trade and commerce with North Africa. Trade between West Africa and the Mediterranean predated Islam, however, North African Muslims intensified the Trans-Saharan trade. North African traders were major actors in introducing Islam into West Africa. Several major trade routes connected Africa below the Sahara with the Mediterranean Middle East, such as Sijilmasa to Awdaghust and Ghadames to Gao. The Sahel, the ecological transition zone between the Sahara desert and forest zone, which spans the African continent, was an intense point of contact between North Africa and communities south of the Sahara. In West Africa, the three great medieval empires of Ghana, Mali, and the Songhay developed in Sahel.

The history of Islam in West Africa can be explained in three stages, containment, mixing, and reform. In the first stage, African kings contained Muslim influence by segregating Muslim communities, in the second stage African rulers blended Islam with local traditions as the population selectively appropriated Islamic practices, and finally in the third stage, African Muslims pressed for reforms in an effort to rid their societies of mixed practices and implement Shariah. This three-phase framework helps sheds light on the historical development of the medieval empires of Ghana, Mali, and Songhay and the 19th century jihads that led to the establishment of the Sokoto Caliphate in Hausaland and the Umarian state in Senegambia.

Containment: Ghana and the Takrur

The early presence of Islam was limited to segregated Muslim communities linked to the trans-Saharan trade. In the 11th century Andalusian geographer, Al-Bakri, reported accounts of Arab and North African Berber settlements in the region. Several factors led to the growth of the Muslim merchant-scholar class in non-Muslim kingdoms. Islam facilitated long distance trade by offering useful sets of tools for merchants including contract law, credit, and information networks. Muslim merchant-scholars also played an important role in non-Muslim kingdoms as advisors and scribes in Ghana. They had the crucial skill of written script, which helped in the administration of kingdoms. Many Muslim were also religious specialists whose amulets were prized by non-Muslims. Merchant-scholars also played a large role in the spread of Islam into the forest zones. These included the Jakhanke merchant-scholars in [name region], the Jula merchants in Mali and the Ivory Coast, and the Hausa merchants during the nineteenth century in Nigeria, Ghana, and Guinea Basau,]. Muslim communities in the forest zones were minority communities often linked to trading diasporas. Many of the traditions in the forest zones still reflect the tradition of Al-Hajj Salim Suwari, a late fifteenth-century Soninke scholar, who focused on responsibilities of Muslims in a non-Muslim society. His tradition, known as the Suwarian tradition, discouraged proselytizing, believing that God would bring people around to Islam in his own ways. This tradition worked for centuries in the forest zone including the present day, where there are vibrant Muslim minority communities. Although modern Ghana is unrelated to the ancient kingdom of Ghana, modern Ghana chose the name as a way of honoring early African history. The boundaries of the ancient Kingdom encompassed the Middle Niger Delta region, which consists of modern-day Mali and parts of present-day Mauritania and Senegal. This region has historically been home to the Soninken Malinke, Wa’kuri and Wangari peoples. Fulanis and the Southern Saharan Sanhaja Berbers also played a prominent role in the spread of Islam in the Niger Delta region. Large towns emerged in the Niger Delta region around 300 A.D. Around the eighth century, Arab documents mentioned ancient Ghana and that Muslims crossed the Sahara into West Africa for trade. North African and Saharan merchants traded salt, horses, dates, and camels from the north with gold, timber, and foodstuff from regions south of the Sahara. Ghana kings, however, did not permit North African and Saharan merchants to stay overnight in the city. This gave rise to one of the major features of Ghana—the dual city; Ghana Kings benefited from Muslim traders, but kept them outside centers of power. From the eighth to the thirteenth century, contact between Muslims and Africans increased and Muslim states began to emerge in the Sahel. Eventually, African kings began to allow Muslims to integrate. Accounts during the eleventh century reported a Muslim state called Takrur in the middle Senegal valley. Around this time, the Almoravid reform movement began in Western Sahara and expanded throughout modern Mauritania, North Africa and Southern Spain. The Almoravids imposed a fundamentalist version of Islam, in an attempt to purify beliefs and practices from syncretistic or heretical beliefs. The Almoravid movement imposed greater uniformity of practice and Islamic law among West African Muslims. The Almoravids captured trade routes and posts, leading to the weakening of the Takruri state. Over the next hundred years, the empire dissolved into a number of small kingdoms.

Mixing: The Empires of Mali and Songhay

Over the next few decades, African rulers began to adopt Islam while ruling over populations with diverse faiths and cultures. Many of these rulers blended Islam with traditional and local practices in what experts call the mixing phase. Over time, the population began to adopt Islam, often selectively appropriating aspects of the faith. The Mali Empire (1215-1450) rose out of the region’s feuding kingdoms. At its height, the empire of Mali composed most of modern Mali, Senegal, parts of Mauritania and Guinea. It was a multi-ethnic state with various religious and cultural groups. Muslims played a prominent role in the court as counselors and advisors. While the empire’s founder, Sunjiata Keita, was not himself a Muslim, by 1300 Mali kings became Muslim. The most famous of them was Mansa Musa (1307-32). He made Islam the state religion and in 1324 went on pilgrimage from Mali to Mecca. Musa’s pilgrimage to Mecca showed up in European records because of his display of wealth and lavish spending. Apparently, his spending devalued the price of gold in Egypt for several years. The famed 14th century traveler Ibn Battuta visited Mali shortly after Mansa Musa’s death. By the fifteenth century, however, Mali dissolved largely due to internal dissent and conflicts with the Saharan Tuareg. Several Muslim polities developed farther east, including the Hausa city-states and the Kingdom of Kanem in modern Northern Nigeria. Hausaland was comprised of a system of city-states (Gobir, Katsina, Kano, Zamfara, Kebbi and Zazzau). The Kingdom of Kanem near Lake Chad flourished as a commercial center from the ninth to 14th century. The state became Muslim during the ninth century. Its successor state was Bornu. Modern day Northern Nigeria comprises much of Hausaland and Bornu in the east. By the 14th century all ruling elites of Hausaland were Muslim, although the majority of the population did not convert until the 18th century jihads. Much like the rulers of earlier Muslims states, the rulers of Hausaland blended local practices and Islam. Emerging from the ruins of the Mali Empire, the Mande Songhay Empire (1430s to 1591) ruled over a diverse and multi-ethnic empire. Although Islam was the state religion, the majority of the population still practiced their traditional belief systems. Many rulers, however, combined local practices with Islam. Sonni Ali, the ruler from 1465-1492, persecuted Muslim scholars, particularly those who criticized pagan practices. During the 13th century, Mansa Musa conquered the Kingdom of Gao. Two centuries later, the kingdom of Gao rose again as the Songhay Empire. Sonni Ali captured much of the Empire of Mali. Under [Aksia Muhammad] 1493-1529), the Songhay’s borders extended far beyond any previous West African empire. The Songhay state patronized Islamic institutions and sponsored public buildings, mosques and libraries. One notable example is the Great Mosque of Jenne, which was built in the 12th or 13th century. The Great Mosque of Jenne remains the largest earthen building in the world. By the 16th century there were several centers of trade and Islamic learning in the Niger Bend region, most notably the famed Timbuktu. Arab chroniclers tell us that the pastoral nomadic Tuareg founded Timbuktu as a trading outpost. The city’s multicultural population, regional trade, and Islamic scholarship fostered a cosmopolitan environment. In 1325, the city’s population was around 10,000. At its apex, in the 16th century, the population is estimated to have been between 30,000 and 50,000. Timbuktu attracted scholars from throughout the Muslim world. The Songhay’s major trading partners were the Merenid dynasty in the Maghrib (north-west Africa) and the Mamluks in Egypt. The Songhay Empire ended when Morocco conquered the state in 1591. The fall of the Songhay marked the decline of big empires in West Africa. Merchant scholars in Timbuktu and other major learning centers dispersed, transferring learning institutions from urban-based merchant families to rural pastoralists throughout the Sahara. During this period there was an alliance between scholars, who were also part of the merchant class, and some warriors who provided protection for trade caravans. Around the 12th and 13th century, mystical Sufi brotherhood orders began to spread in the region. Sufi orders played an integral role in the social order of African Muslim societies and the spread of Islam through the region well into the 20th century.

Reform in the Nineteenth Century: Umarian Jihad in Senegambia and the Sokoto Caliphate in Hausaland

The 19th century jihad movements best exemplify the third phase in the development Islam in West Africa. Specialists have highlighted the ways in which literate Muslims became increasingly aware of Islamic doctrine and began to demand reforms during this period. This period was significant in that it marks a shift in Muslim communities that practiced Islam mixed with “pagan” rituals and practices to societies that completely adopted Islamic values and established Shariah Scholars have debated the origins of the 19th century West African jihads. The first known jihad in West Africa was in Mauritania during the 17th century. At that time, Mauritanian society was divided along scholar and warrior lineages. The scholar Nasir al-Din led a failed jihad called Sharr Bubba. Unlike the failed jihad in Mauritania, the 19th century jihad movements in Senegambia and Hausaland (in what is now northern Nigeria) successfully overthrew the established order and transformed the ruling and landowning class. In 1802, Uthman Dan Fodio, a Fulani scholar, led a major jihad. With the help of a large Fulani cavalry and Hausa peasants, Uthman Dan Fodio overthrew the region’s Hausa rulers and replaced them with Fulani emirs. The movement led to centralization of power in the Muslim community, education reforms, and transformations of law. Uthman Dan Fodio also sparked a literary revival with a production of religious work that included Arabic texts and vernacular written in Arabic script. His heirs continued the legacy of literary production and education reform. Uthman Dan Fodio’s movement inspired a number of jihads in the region. A notable example was the jihad of al Hajj Umar Tal, a Tukulor from the Senegambia region. In the 1850s, Umar Tal returned from pilgrimage claiming to have received spiritual authority over the West African Tijani Sufi order. From the 1850s to 1860s, he conquered three Bambara kingdoms. After Tal’s defeat by the French at Médine in 1857 and the subsequent defeat of his son in the 1880s, his followers fled westward spreading the influence of the Tijani order in Northern Nigeria. Although the French controlled the region, colonial authorities met another formidable enemy. Samori Toure rose up against the French and gathered a 30,000 strong army. Following his death, French forces defeated Toure’s son in 1901. The French occupation of Senegal forced the final development of Islamic practice where leaders of Sufi orders became allies with colonial administrators. Although European powers led to the decline of the Umarian state and the Sokoto Caliphate, colonial rule did little to stop the spread of Islam in West Africa. The British used anti-slavery rhetoric as they began their conquest of the Sokoto Caliphate in 1897. The Sokoto Caliphate ended in 1903, when British troops conquered the state. Colonial authorities attempted to maintain the established social order and ruled through Northern Nigerian emirs. Despite the efforts of colonial authorities, colonialism had far reaching effects on Northern Nigerian Muslim society. Modern communication and transportation infrastructure facilitated increased exchange between Muslim communities. As a result, Islam began to spread rapidly in new urban centers and regions such as Yoruba land. Similarly in the French Sudan, Islam actually spread in rates far greater than the previous centuries. Although Muslims lost political power, Muslim communities made rapid inroads in the West Africa during the early 20th century.

The three stages of containment, mixing, and reform can shed light on the historical developments of Islam in this region. The trans-Saharan trade was an important gateway for the spread of Islam in Africa. The legacy of the medieval empires and nineteenth century reform movements continues to have relevance in present day Senegal, Gambia, Mali, Nigeria, Burkina Faso, Nigeria, as well as many neighboring communities. Muslim communities have existed in West Africa for over a millennium, pointing to the fact that Islam is a significant part of the African landscape.

For Further Reading:

  • "Western Sudan, 500–1000 A.D.". In Timeline of Art History . New York: The Metropolitan Museum of Art, 2000–. http://www.metmuseum.org/toah/ht/06/sfw/ht06sfw.htm (October 2001)
  • "Western and Central Sudan, 1000–1400 A.D.". In Timeline of Art History . New York: The Metropolitan Museum of Art, 2000–. http://www.metmuseum.org/toah/ht/07/sfw/ht07sfw.htm (October 2001)
  • "Western and Central Sudan, 1400–1600 A.D.". In Timeline of Art History . New York: The Metropolitan Museum of Art, 2000–. http://www.metmuseum.org/toah/ht/08/sfw/ht08sfw.htm (October 2002)
  • "Western and Central Sudan, 1600–1800 A.D.". In Timeline of Art History . New York: The Metropolitan Museum of Art, 2000–. http://www.metmuseum.org/toah/ht/09/sfw/ht09sfw.htm (October 2003)
  • David Robinson. Muslim Societies in African History . New York: Cambridge University Press, 2004.
  • Nehemia Levtzion and Randall L. Pouwels (eds). The History of Islam in Africa . Athens OH: Ohio University Press, 2000.
  • Spencer Trimingham, History of Islam in West Africa .New York: Oxford University Press, 1962.

how did islam travel to africa

Featured Topics

Featured series.

A series of random questions answered by Harvard experts.

Explore the Gazette

Read the latest.

Exterior of Tiffany flagship

For this ring, I thee sue 

Cass R. Sunstein (left) speaks with Benjamin Eidelson, Professor of Law, on his new book "Campus Free Speech."

Speech is never totally free

Lined up electric vehicle cars.

EVs fight warming but are costly. Why aren’t we driving $10,000 Chinese imports?

A deeper sense of muslim africa.

Harvard Staff Writer

HDS author elucidates history, scholarship

Ousmane Kane , the Prince Alwaleed Bin Talal Professor of Contemporary Islamic Religion and Society and professor of Near Eastern Languages and Civilizations in the Faculty of Arts and Sciences, will discuss his book, “Beyond Timbuktu: An Intellectual History of Muslim West Africa,” at the Center for the Study of World Religions on April 3 at 5:15 p.m. The talk is co-sponsored by the Islam in Africa Speaker Series.

Kane delivered the keynote address  in February at the Divinity School conference “Text, Knowledge, and Practice: The Meaning of Scholarship in Muslim Africa.”

The Gazette interviewed Kane to illuminate the roots and influence of Islam in Africa, which is home to nearly 30 percent of the world’s Muslims.

GAZETTE : What is the most common misconception the West has about African Muslims?

KANE: Black Africa has been represented in academia as well as in popular representations as a continent of warring tribes. Look at the coverage of Africa in most TV channels. It is most of the time about tribal conflicts. What I argue in my book is that large sections of West African peoples have, in the past and the present, proven their ability to transcend parochial identities and differences in a common cause and have indeed claimed their independence of thought and common destiny. More than anything else, this is embodied in a long literary tradition in the Arabic and in African languages written with the Arabic script. Unfortunately, this literary tradition has been obscured by Western discourses of the past century that tended to represent black Africa essentially as a continent of orality. In doing so, these discourses have obscured its literary tradition.

GAZETTE: How did Islam spread from the Arabian Peninsula to the rest of Africa?

KANE:  Islam has a very long history in Africa. In fact, it was introduced in the African continent even before it spread in Arabia, let alone the neighboring countries of the Arabian Peninsula. The prophet Muhammad sent dozens of his companions to Ethiopia before the beginning of the Muslim calendar. During the first century of the Muslim calendar, Islam spread from Egypt through the Red Sea and the East African coastal areas on one hand, and from Egypt across the desert to the rest of North Africa on the other hand. It is from North Africa that it was introduced to West Africa across the Sahara.

GAZETTE:  Your book’s title is “Beyond Timbuktu: An Intellectual History of Muslim West Africa.” What is the significance of Timbuktu, the ancient city in Mali, in the history of Islam?

KANE: Timbuktu is famous as a great center of trade and Muslim learning from Islam’s Golden Age. It is renowned for its many old mosques and colleges and for its collections of rare Arabic manuscripts. For centuries, it has attracted Muslim scholars and merchants, but Timbuktu was not unique. It was only one among many scholarly centers that flourished in West Africa in the last several centuries. My book charts the rise of Muslim learning from the beginning not just in Timbuktu, but in other parts of West Africa as well, to the present. It also examines the shifting contexts that have influenced the production and dissemination of Islamic knowledge.

GAZETTE: What other places in West Africa have the same significance as Timbuktu? Where do the majority of Muslims in Africa live?

KANE: Other prominent centers of Muslim learning in West Africa include Agadez [Niger], Walata and Shinqit [Mauritania], Djenné [Mali], Kaolack, Pire, Koki [Senegal], and Kano, Katsina, and Borno [Nigeria], to cite just a few. The number of Muslims in Africa is estimated between 450 and 500 million. This is close to a third of the Muslim global population. The overwhelming majority live in the northern half of the continent above the Equator. In North African countries like Morocco, Algeria, Tunisia, Libya, Egypt, and West African countries like Senegal, Mali, Mauritania, Niger, more than 90 percent of the population is Muslim. With more than 80 million Muslims, Nigeria has the sixth largest Muslim population in the world after Indonesia, Pakistan, India, Bangladesh, and Egypt.

GAZETTE: What are West Africa’s contributions to the development of Islam?

KANE: Africans have influenced scholarship throughout the Islamic world for more than a millennium. This has been fully documented by recent research on the literary cultures of West Africa, and particularly the manuscript heritage. With the spread of Arabic literacy, African scholars developed a rich tradition of debate over orthodoxy and meaning in Islam. The rise of such a tradition was hardly disconnected from centers of Islamic learning outside of Africa. In Timbuktu, Cairo, Mecca, and Baghdad, African scholars have played significant roles in the development of virtually every field of Islamic sciences. A glance at the writings and curriculum of West African Muslims shows that they cite works from the entire Muslim world. This is evidence that they participate in a global network of scholarly exchange.

GAZETTE: Why is it important to write a book about Muslims in West Africa and Africa in general?

KANE: I hope that the book will correct misconceptions in both the West and the Middle East that West Africa’s Muslim heritage represents a minor thread in Islam’s larger tapestry. I also hope that they realize that African Muslims in general have never been isolated. Neither the Red Sea nor the Sahara had ever been an insurmountable barrier to communication. On the contrary, they were bridges that allowed Arabs and Black African Muslims to maintain close relations through trade, diplomacy, and intellectual and spiritual exchange.

Share this article

You might like.

Unhappy suitor wants $70,000 engagement gift back. Now court must decide whether 

Cass R. Sunstein (left) speaks with Benjamin Eidelson, Professor of Law, on his new book "Campus Free Speech."

Cass Sunstein suggests universities look to First Amendment as they struggle to craft rules in wake of disruptive protests

Lined up electric vehicle cars.

Experts say tension between trade, green-tech policies hampers climate change advances; more targeted response needed

Harvard releases race data for Class of 2028

Cohort is first to be impacted by Supreme Court’s admissions ruling

Parkinson’s may take a ‘gut-first’ path

Damage to upper GI lining linked to future risk of Parkinson’s disease, says new study

Professor tailored AI tutor to physics course. Engagement doubled.

Preliminary findings inspire other large Harvard classes to test approach this fall

  • Albalagh.net
  • AnswersToFatawa
  • Arij Canada
  • Askimam.org
  • Askmufti.co.za
  • AskOurImam.com
  • CouncilofUlama.co.za
  • Darulfiqh.com
  • Darulifta Azaadville
  • Darulifta Deoband Waqf
  • Darulifta-Deoband.com
  • Daruliftaa.com
  • DaruliftaaMW.com
  • DaruliftaaZambia.com
  • DarulIftaBirmingham
  • Darulihsan.com
  • DarulUloomTT.net
  • Fatwa-TT.com
  • Fatwa.org.au
  • FatwaCentre.org
  • HadithAnswers.com
  • IslamicPortal.co.uk
  • IslamicSolutions.org
  • Jamia Binoria
  • Mahmoodiyah
  • Mathabah.org
  • Muftionline.co.za
  • Muftisays.com
  • MuslimaCoaching.com
  • Seekersguidance.org
  • ShariahBoard.org
  • Tafseer Raheemi
  • TheMufti.com
  • ZamzamAcademy.com
  • BinBayyah.net
  • Darul Iftaa Jordan
  • Shafiifiqh.com
  • HanbaliDisciples.com
  • TheHanbaliMadhhab.com
  • Ask Question
  • Lailatul Qadr

IslamQA

Home » Hanafi Fiqh » Askimam.org » How was Islam spread in Africa?

Related Q&A

  • Did Al-Najashi convert to Islam during the Prophet's lifetime and which book mentions it?
  • What is the meaning of watching some one with some sahaaba preparing for a mission ?
  • Were there differences in the copies of the Quran given to the Sahaaba [radhiallaahu anhu]?
  • When a person has an argument with a non Muslim or with a Shia defending Islam or defending Sahabah, even if it is via the internet, does he…
  • As it is apparent that Muslim Ummah is in troubles in contemporary times, shouldnt the righteous ulema of ihlesunnat wal jamah work for…
  • How did Islam spread in Indo-pak area?

How was Islam spread in Africa?

Where did Islam first land in Africa? (the year) Where did it spread to, by whom and how?

Many Sahaaba (Radhiallaahu Anhum) first migrated to Abyssinia today known as Ethiopia. The Abyssinian King Najashy granted the Sahaaba asylum there and permitted them to practise and propagate Islam. Therefore, Islam in North Africa first spread to Abyssinia. Refer below. and Allah Ta’ala Knows Best Mufti Ebrahim Desai —————- ISLAMIC HISTORY IN RUNNING The Umayyads The Umayyad caliphate established in 661 was to last for about a century. During this time Damascus became the capital of an Islamic world which stretched from the western borders of China to southern France. Not only did the Islamic conquests continue during this period through North Africa to Spain and France in the West and to Sind, Central Asia and Transoxiana in the East, but the basic social and legal institutions of the newly founded Islamic world were established. The Abbasids The Abbasids, who succeeded the Umayyads, shifted the capital to Baghdad which soon developed into an incomparable center of learning and culture as well as the administrative and political heart of a vast world. They ruled for over 500 years but gradually their power waned and they remained only symbolic rulers bestowing legitimacy upon various sultans and princes who wielded actual military power. The Abbasid caliphate was finally abolished when Hulagu, the Mongol ruler, captured Baghdad in 1258, destroying much of the city including its incomparable libraries. While the Abbasids ruled in Baghdad, a number of powerful dynasties such as the Fatimids, Ayyubids and Mamluks held power in Egypt, Syria and Palestine. The most important event in this area as far as the relation between Islam and the Western world was concerned was the series of Crusades declared by the Pope and espoused by various European kings. The purpose, although political, was outwardly to recapture the Holy Land and especially Jerusalem for Christianity. Although there was at the beginning some success and local European rule was set up in parts of Syria and Palestine, Muslims finally prevailed and in 1187 Saladin, the great Muslim leader, recaptured Jerusalem and defeated the Crusaders. North Africa and Spain When the Abbasids captured Damascus, one of the Umayyad princes escaped and made the long journey from there to Spain to found Umayyad rule there, thus beginning the golden age of Islam in Spain. Cordoba was established as the capital and soon became Europe’s greatest city not only in population but from the point of view of its cultural and intellectual life. The Umayyads ruled over two centuries until they weakened and were replaced by local rulers. Meanwhile in North Africa, various local dynasties held sway until two powerful Berber dynasties succeeded in uniting much of North Africa and also Spain in the 12th and 13th centuries. After them this area was ruled once again by local dynasties such as the Sharifids of Morocco who still rule in that country. As for Spain itself, Muslim power continued to wane until the last Muslim dynasty was defeated in Granada in 1492 thus bringing nearly eight hundred years of Muslim rule in Spain to an end. After the Mongol Invasion The Mongols devastated the eastern lands of Islam and ruled from the Sinai Desert to India for a century. But they soon converted to Islam and became known as the Il-Khanids. They were in turn succeeded by Timur and his descendents who made Samarqand their capital and ruled from 1369 to 1500. The sudden rise of Timur delayed the formation and expansion of the Ottoman empire but soon the Ottomans became the dominant power in the Islamic world. Ottoman Empire From humble origins the Turks rose to dominate over the whole of Anatolia and even parts of Europe. In 1453 Mehmet the Conqueror captured Constantinople and put an end to the Byzantine empire. The Ottomans conquered much of eastem Europe and nearly the whole of the Arab world, only Morocco and Mauritania in the West and Yemen, Hadramaut and parts of the Arabian peninsula remaining beyond their control. They reached their zenith of power with Suleyman the Magnificent whose armies reached Hungary and Austria. From the 17th century onward with the rise of Westem European powers and later Russia, the power of the Ottomans began to wane. But they nevertheless remained a force to be reckoned with until the First World War when they were defeated by the Westem nations. Soon thereafter Kamal Ataturk gained power in Turkey and abolished the six centuries of rule of the Ottomans in 1924. Persia While the Ottomans were concerned mostly with the western front of their empire, to the east in Persia a new dynasty called the Safavids came to power in 1502. The Safavids established a powerful state of their own which flourished for over two centuries and became known for the flowering of the arts. Their capital, Isfahan, became one of the most beautiful cities with its blue tiled mosques and exquisite houses. The Afghan invasion of 1736 put an end to Safavid rule and prepared the independence of Afghanistan which occurred formally in the 19th century. Persia itself fell into turmoil until Nader Shah, the last Oriental conqueror, reunited the country and even conquered India. But the rule of the dynasty established by him was short-lived. The Zand dynasty soon took over to be overthrown by the Qajars in 1779 who made Tehran their capital and ruled until 1921 when they were in turn replaced by the Pahlavis. India Islam entered into the land east of the Indus River peacefully. Gradually Muslims gained political power beginning in the early 13th century. But this period which marked the expansion of both Islam and Islamic culture came to an end with the conquest of much of India in 1526 by Babur, one of the Timurid princes. He established the powerful Mogul empire which produced such famous rulers as Akbar, Jahangir, and Shah Jahan and which lasted, despite the gradual rise of British power in India, until 1857 when it was officially abolished. Malaysia and Indonesia Farther east in the Malay world, Islam began to spread in the 12th century in northern Sumatra and soon Muslim kingdoms were established in Java, Sumatra and mainland Malaysia. Despite the colonization of the Malay world, Islam spread in that area covering present day Indonesia, Malaysia, the southern Philippines and southern Thailand, and is still continuing in islands farther east. Africa Islam entered into East Africa at the very beginning of the Islamic period but remained confined to the coast for some time, only the Sudan and Somaliland becoming gradually both Arabized and Islamized. West Africa felt the presence of Islam through North African traders who travelled with their camel caravans south of the Sahara. By the 14th century there were already Muslim sultanates in such areas as Mali, and Timbuctu in West Africa and Harar in East Africa had become seats of Islamic learning. Gradually Islam penetrated both inland and southward. There also appeared major charismatic figures who inspired intense resistance against European domination. The process of the Islamization of Africa did not cease during the colonial period and continues even today with the result that most Africans are now Muslims carrying on a tradition which has had practically as long a history in certain areas of sub-Saharan Africa as Islam itself. Moulana Khalid Dhorat Dar al-Salam Islamic Research Institute

This answer was collected from Askimam.org, which is operated under the supervision of Mufti Ebrahim Desai from South Africa.

Read answers with similar topics:

Random Q&A

I gave my wife one divorce then we found out she is pregnant,does this divorce still count, how to convince my wife to move-in with me, is it ok to use on her because we couldnt find an alternative medicine which cures her allergy….i get frustrated when my mother talks or says anything i know i shouldnt hate her but i know how she treated my late father and still she have affairs with different ppl., six good deeds, bequest of the deceased to be buried in a specific place, does the wife have equal rights regarding intercourse, more answers….

  • What is SHAB-E-BARAAT? Please quote the Ahadith relating to this. Are there any Hadith that support performing Special Ibadaat during this Night?
  • My wife does not whish to be with me any more and wants talaaq. I undertand her, she is very young and im about 9 years older than her.
  • Surah Taariq v.6-7 and science
  • Fallible Khalifah
  • Ibadhi Sect
  • I am intrested in a guy to get marry and he is equally intrested, can you refer something to read for Allah to tie us in this relationship.

Latest Q&A

  • Male body hair
  • Becoming pure from mensturation
  • Going out with brother’s fiancé
  • Student loans/finance
  • Inheritance of undelivered gift
  • Questions Around Wiping On Socks

Indexed Websites

Privacy overview.

  • Tools and Resources
  • Customer Services
  • African Diaspora
  • Afrocentrism
  • Archaeology
  • Central Africa
  • Colonial Conquest and Rule
  • Cultural History
  • Early States and State Formation in Africa
  • East Africa and Indian Ocean
  • Economic History
  • Historical Linguistics
  • Historical Preservation and Cultural Heritage
  • Historiography and Methods
  • Image of Africa
  • Intellectual History
  • Invention of Tradition
  • Language and History
  • Legal History
  • Medical History
  • Military History
  • North Africa and the Gulf
  • Northeastern Africa
  • Oral Traditions
  • Political History
  • Religious History
  • Slavery and Slave Trade
  • Social History
  • Southern Africa
  • West Africa
  • Women’s History
  • Share Facebook LinkedIn Twitter

Article contents

The history of islam in east africa.

  • Felicitas Becker Felicitas Becker Centre of African Studies, Cambridge University
  • https://doi.org/10.1093/acrefore/9780190277734.013.151
  • Published online: 25 June 2018

The history of Islam in East Africa stretches back to around 1000 CE. Until the mid-20th century, it remained largely confined to the coast and closely bound up with the history of the Swahili towns situated on it. The Swahili language remains central to many East African Muslims, hence the occasionally heard phrase, “Swahili Islam.” East African Muslims are mostly Shafiites and some belong to Sufi orders, especially Qadiriyya and Shadhiliyya. Since c . 1850, Islam, with many variations in ritual, has become the religion of speakers of a multitude of languages across the region, second only to Christianity. The region’s independent nation-states initially promised equality for all religions within a secular order. Since c . 1990, though, the minority status of East African Muslims has fed into a multitude of grievances related to the region’s economic and political impasses. This situation has led to growing movements of Islamic preaching and activism, supported by increased contacts with congregations elsewhere in the Indian Ocean. At times, they have influenced electoral politics, especially in Zanzibar, where Islamic activism resonates with fear of marginalization by the mainland. In Kenya, Somali-influenced Islamist terrorists committed a series of atrocities in the 2010s. East African governments, in turn, have been proactive in tracking and disrupting such networks, and in Kenya, the government engaged in targeted assassination. Nevertheless, peaceful coexistence between Muslims and adherents of other religions remains the norm in East Africa, and its dynamics are often poorly understood.

  • Swahili Islam
  • East African Islam
  • East African Islamism
  • Muslim discontent
  • Islam and postcolonial politics
  • Islam and nation-states

You do not currently have access to this article

Please login to access the full content.

Access to the full content requires a subscription

Printed from Oxford Research Encyclopedias, African History. Under the terms of the licence agreement, an individual user may print out a single article for personal use (for details see Privacy Policy and Legal Notice).

date: 13 September 2024

  • Cookie Policy
  • Privacy Policy
  • Legal Notice
  • Accessibility
  • [66.249.64.20|185.39.149.46]
  • 185.39.149.46

Character limit 500 /500

how did islam travel to africa

  • History Classics
  • Your Profile
  • Find History on Facebook (Opens in a new window)
  • Find History on Twitter (Opens in a new window)
  • Find History on YouTube (Opens in a new window)
  • Find History on Instagram (Opens in a new window)
  • Find History on TikTok (Opens in a new window)
  • This Day In History
  • History Podcasts
  • History Vault

Why Moroccan Scholar Ibn Battuta May Be the Greatest Explorer of all Time

By: Evan Andrews

Updated: September 11, 2023 | Original: July 20, 2017

Explorer Ibn Battuta on horseback. Behind him, a map of his journey.

The title of “history’s most famous traveler” usually goes to Marco Polo, the great Venetian wayfarer who visited China in the 13th century. For sheer distance covered, however, Polo trails far behind the Muslim scholar Ibn Battuta. Though little known outside the Islamic world, Battuta spent half his life tramping across vast swaths of the Eastern Hemisphere.

Moving by sea, by camel caravan and on foot, he ventured into over 40 modern day nations, often putting himself in extreme danger just to satisfy his wanderlust. When he finally returned home after 29 years, he recorded his escapades in a hulking travelogue known as the Rihla . Though modern scholars often question the veracity of Battuta's writings—he may never have visited China, for example, and many of his accounts of foreign lands appear to have been plagiarized from other authors' works—the Rihla is a fascinating look into the world of a 14th-century vagabond.

Born in Tangier, Morocco, Ibn Battuta came of age in a family of Islamic judges. In 1325, at age 21, he left his homeland for the Middle East. He intended to complete his hajj—the Muslim pilgrimage to the holy city of Mecca—but he also wished to study Islamic law along the way. “I set out alone,” he later remembered, “having neither fellow-traveler in whose companionship I might find cheer, nor caravan whose party I might join, but swayed by an overmastering impulse within me and a desire long-cherished in my bosom to visit these illustrious sanctuaries.”

Battuta began his journey riding solo on a donkey, but soon linked up with a pilgrim caravan as it snaked its way east across North Africa. The route was rugged and bandit infested, and the young traveler soon developed a fever so severe that he was forced to tie himself to his saddle to avoid collapsing. Nevertheless, he still found time during one stopover to wed a young woman—the first of some 10 wives he would eventually marry and then divorce during his travels.

how did islam travel to africa

9 Intrepid Women Explorers

From a Viking 'far traveler' to a Soviet cosmonaut, these fearless women blazed daring new trails.

The Viking Explorer Who Beat Columbus to America

Leif Eriksson Day commemorates the Norse explorer believed to have led the first European expedition to North America.

6 Explorers Who Disappeared

These famous explorers journeyed to the far reaches of the earth, only to never be seen again.

In Egypt, Battuta studied Islamic law and toured Alexandria and the metropolis of Cairo, which he called “peerless in beauty and splendor.” He then continued on to Mecca, where he took part in the hajj. His travels might have ended there, but having completed his pilgrimage, he decided to continue wandering the Muslim world, or “Dar al-Islam.” Battuta claimed to be driven by a dream in which a large bird took him on its wing and “made a long flight towards the east…and left me there.” A holy man had interpreted the dream to mean that Battuta would roam across the earth, and the young Moroccan intended to fulfill the prophecy.

Battuta’s next few years were a whirlwind of travel. He joined a caravan and toured Persia and Iraq, and later ventured north to what is now Azerbaijan. Following a sojourn in Mecca, he trekked across Yemen and made a sea voyage to the Horn of Africa. From there, he visited the Somali city of Mogadishu before dipping below the equator and exploring the coasts of Kenya and Tanzania.

Ibn Battuta in Egypt. Illustration by Paul Dumouza.

Upon leaving Africa, Battuta hatched a plan to travel to India, where he hoped to secure a lucrative post as a “qadi,” or Islamic judge. He followed a winding route east, first cutting through Egypt and Syria before sailing for Turkey. As he always did in Muslim-controlled lands, he relied on his status as an Islamic scholar to win hospitality from locals. At many points in his travels, he was showered with gifts of fine clothes, horses and even concubines and slaves.

From Turkey, Battuta crossed the Black Sea and entered the domain of a Golden Horde Khan known as Uzbeg. He was welcomed at Uzbeg’s court, and later accompanied one of the Khan’s wives to Constantinople. Battuta stayed in the Byzantine city for a month, visiting the Hagia Sophia and even receiving a brief audience with the emperor. Having never ventured to a large non-Muslim city, he was stunned by the “almost innumerable” collection of Christian churches within its walls.

Battuta next traveled east across the Eurasian steppe before entering India via Afghanistan and the Hindu Kush. Arriving in the city of Delhi in 1334, he won employment as a judge under Muhammad Tughluq, a powerful Islamic sultan. Battuta passed several years in the cushy job and even married and fathered children, but he eventually grew wary of the mercurial sultan, who was known to maim and kill his enemies—sometimes by tossing them to elephants with swords attached to their tusks. A chance to escape finally presented itself in 1341, when the sultan selected Battuta as his envoy to the Mongol court of China. Still thirsty for adventure, the Moroccan set out at the head of a large caravan brimming with gifts and slaves.

The trip to the Orient would prove to be the most harrowing chapter of Battuta’s odyssey. Hindu rebels harassed his group during their journey to the Indian coast, and Battuta was later kidnapped and robbed of everything but his pants. He managed to make it to the port of Calicut, but on the eve of an ocean voyage, his ships blew out to sea in a storm and sank, killing many in his party.

Ibn Battuta, Moroccan explorer, in Egypt. Illustration by Leon Benett from book by Jules Verne, 1878

The string of disasters left Battuta stranded and disgraced. He was loath to return to Delhi and face the sultan, however, so he elected to make a sea voyage south to the Indian Ocean archipelago of the Maldives. He remained in the idyllic islands for the next year, gorging on coconuts, taking several wives and once again serving as an Islamic judge. Battuta might have stayed in the Maldives even longer, but following a falling out with its rulers, he resumed his journey to China. After making a stopover in Sri Lanka, he rode merchant vessels through Southeast Asia. In 1345, four years after first leaving India, he arrived at the bustling Chinese port of Quanzhou.

Battuta described Mongol China as “the safest and best country for the traveler” and praised its natural beauty, but he also branded its inhabitants “pagans” and “infidels.” Distressed by the unfamiliar customs on display, the pious traveler stuck close to the country’s Muslim communities and offered only vague accounts of metropolises such as Hangzhou, which he called “the biggest city I have seen on the face of the earth.” Historians still debate just how far he went, but he claimed to have roamed as far north as Beijing and crossed through the famous Grand Canal.

China marked the beginning of the end of Battuta’s travels. Having reached the edge of the known world, he finally turned around and journeyed home to Morocco, arriving back in Tangier in 1349. Both of Battuta’s parents had died by then, so he only remained for a short while before making a jaunt to Spain. He then embarked on a multi-year excursion across the Sahara to the Mali Empire, where he visited Timbuktu.

Battuta had never kept journals during his adventures, but when he returned to Morocco for good in 1354, the country’s sultan ordered him to compile a travelogue. He spent the next year dictating his story to a writer named Ibn Juzayy. The result was an oral history called A Gift to Those Who Contemplate the Wonders of Cities and the Marvels of Traveling , better known as the Rihla  (or “travels”). Though not particularly popular in its day, the book now stands as one of the most vivid and wide-ranging accounts of the 14th century Islamic world.

Following the completion of the Rihla , Ibn Battuta all but vanished from the historical record. He is believed to have worked as a judge in Morocco and died sometime around 1368, but little else is known about him. It appears that after a lifetime spent on the road, the great wanderer was finally content to stay in one place.

how did islam travel to africa

Sign up for Inside History

Get HISTORY’s most fascinating stories delivered to your inbox three times a week.

By submitting your information, you agree to receive emails from HISTORY and A+E Networks. You can opt out at any time. You must be 16 years or older and a resident of the United States.

More details : Privacy Notice | Terms of Use | Contact Us

ENCYCLOPEDIC ENTRY

Mansa musa (musa i of mali).

Mansa Musa (Musa I of Mali) was the king of the ancient empire of Mali in West Africa.

Geography, Human Geography, Social Studies, Ancient Civilizations, World History

Timbuktu, Henrich Barth Painting

The fame of Mansa Musa and his phenomenal wealth spread as he traveled on his hajj to Mecca. Afterward, he put himself and his kingdom, West Africa's Mali, on the map, literally. Mali's Timbuktu was known for its schools and libraries.

Photograph by FL Historical 1D

The fame of Mansa Musa and his phenomenal wealth spread as he traveled on his hajj to Mecca. Afterward, he put himself and his kingdom, West Africa's Mali, on the map, literally. Mali's Timbuktu was known for its schools and libraries.

Mansa Musa (Musa I of Mali) was the ruler of the kingdom of Mali from 1312 C.E. to 1337 C.E. During his reign, Mali was one of the richest kingdoms of Africa, and Mansa Musa was among the richest individuals in the world. The ancient kingdom of Mali spread across parts of modern-day Mali, Senegal, the Gambia, Guinea, Niger, Nigeria, Chad, Mauritania, and Burkina Faso. Mansa Musa developed cities like Timbuktu and Gao into important cultural centers. He also brought architects from the Middle East and across Africa to design new buildings for his cities. Mansa Musa turned the kingdom of Mali into a sophisticated center of learning in the Islamic world. Mansa Musa came to power in 1312 C.E., after the previous king, Abu Bakr II, disappeared at sea. Mansa Abu Bakr II had departed on a large fleet of ships to explore the Atlantic Ocean, and never returned. Mansa Musa inherited a kingdom that was already wealthy, but his work in expanding trade made Mali the wealthiest kingdom in Africa. His riches came from mining significant salt and gold deposits in the Mali kingdom. Elephant ivory was another major source of wealth. When Mansa Musa went on a pilgrimage ( hajj ) to Mecca in 1324 C.E., his journey through Egypt caused quite a stir. The kingdom of Mali was relatively unknown outside of West Africa until this event. Arab writers from the time said that he travelled with an entourage of tens of thousands of people and dozens of camels, each carrying 136 kilograms (300 pounds) of gold. While in Cairo, Mansa Musa met with the Sultan of Egypt, and his caravan spent and gave away so much gold that the overall value of gold decreased in Egypt for the next 12 years. Stories of his fabulous wealth even reached Europe. The Catalan Atlas, created in 1375 C.E. by Spanish cartographers , shows West Africa dominated by a depiction of Mansa Musa sitting on a throne, holding a nugget of gold in one hand and a golden staff in the other. After the publication of this atlas, Mansa Musa became cemented in the global imagination as a figure of stupendous wealth. After his return from Mecca, Mansa Musa began to revitalize cities in his kingdom. He built mosques and large public buildings in cities like Gao and, most famously, Timbuktu. Timbuktu became a major Islamic university center during the 14th century due to Mansa Musa’s developments. Mansa Musa brought architects and scholars from across the Islamic world into his kingdom, and the reputation of the Mali kingdom grew. The kingdom of Mali reached its greatest extent around the same time, a bustling, wealthy kingdom thanks to Mansa Musa’s expansion and administration. Mansa Musa died in 1337 and was succeeded by his sons. His skillful administration left his empire well-off at the time of his death, but eventually, the empire fell apart. Well after his death, Mansa Musa remained engrained in the imagination of the world as a symbol of fabulous wealth. However, his riches are only one part of his legacy, and he is also remembered for his Islamic faith, promotion of scholarship, and patronage of culture in Mali.

Media Credits

The audio, illustrations, photos, and videos are credited beneath the media asset, except for promotional images, which generally link to another page that contains the media credit. The Rights Holder for media is the person or group credited.

Production Managers

Program specialists, last updated.

October 19, 2023

User Permissions

For information on user permissions, please read our Terms of Service. If you have questions about how to cite anything on our website in your project or classroom presentation, please contact your teacher. They will best know the preferred format. When you reach out to them, you will need the page title, URL, and the date you accessed the resource.

If a media asset is downloadable, a download button appears in the corner of the media viewer. If no button appears, you cannot download or save the media.

Text on this page is printable and can be used according to our Terms of Service .

Interactives

Any interactives on this page can only be played while you are visiting our website. You cannot download interactives.

Related Resources

how did islam travel to africa

The Prophet Muhammad and the Origins of Islam

The rise of Islam is intrinsically linked with the Prophet Muhammad, believed by Muslims to be the last in a long line of prophets that includes Moses and Jesus. Because Muhammad was the chosen recipient and messenger of the word of God through the divine revelations, Muslims from all walks of life strive to follow his example. After the holy Qur'an, the sayings of the Prophet ( hadith ) and descriptions of his way of life ( sunna ) are the most important Muslim texts.

Early Life Muhammad was born into the most powerful tribe in Mecca, the Quraish, around 570 A.D. The power of the Quraish derived from their role as successful merchants. Several trade routes intersected at Mecca, allowing the Quraish to control trade along the west coast of Arabia, north to Syria, and south to Yemen.

Mecca was home to two widely venerated polytheistic cults whose gods were thought to protect its lucrative trade. After working for several years as a merchant, Muhammad was hired by Khadija, a wealthy widow, to ensure the safe passage of her caravans to Syria. They eventually married.

Divine Revelations When he was roughly forty, Muhammad began having visions and hearing voices. Searching for clarity, he would sometimes meditate at Mount Hira, near Mecca. On one of these occasions, the Archangel Gabriel ( Jibra'il in Arabic) appeared to him and instructed him to recite "in the name of [your] lord." This was the first of many revelations that became the basis of the Qur'an, the holy book of Islam. These early revelations pointed to the existence of a single God, contradicting the polytheistic beliefs of the pre-Islamic Arabian Peninsula.

Initially overwhelmed by the significance of what was being revealed to him, Muhammad found unflinching support in his wife and slowly began to attract followers. His strong monotheistic message angered many of the Meccan merchants. They were afraid that trade, which they believed was protected by the pagan gods, would suffer. From that point forward, Muhammad was ostracized in Mecca. For a time, the influence and status of his wife and his uncle, Abu Talib, the chief of the clan, protected Muhammad from persecution. After they died, however, Muhammad's situation in Mecca became dire.

The Hijra Emigration became the only hope for Muhammad and his followers' survival. In 622, they headed to Medina, another oasis town, where they were promised freedom to practice their religion. The move from Mecca to Medina is known as the hijra —the flight—and marks year 1 of the Islamic, or hijri , calendar.

Spreading the Message of Islam In Medina, Muhammad continued to receive divine revelations and built an ever-expanding community around the new faith. The conflict with the Quraish continued, but after several years of violent clashes, Mecca surrendered. Muhammad and his followers soon returned and took over the city, destroying all its pagan idols and spreading their belief in one God.

The Night Journey and Ascension of the Prophet Accounts of the ascension ( mi'raj  ) of Muhammad have captured the imaginations of writers and painters for centuries. One night, while the Prophet was sleeping, the Archangel Gabriel came and led him on a journey. Mounted on the heavenly steed Buraq , Muhammad traveled from the Ka'ba in Mecca to the "Farthest Mosque," which Muslims believe to be the Al-Aqsa Mosque in Jerusalem. There he prayed with other prophets such as Moses, Abraham, and Jesus, and ascended to the skies, where he was led by Gabriel through Paradise and Hell, and finally came face to face with God. He then returned to earth to continue spreading the message of Islam. According to Islamic belief, Muhammad was the only person to see Heaven and Hell while still alive.

After the Prophet's Death: Emergence of Shi'i and Sunni Sects of Islam When Muhammad died in 632, he had not named a successor. One faction, the Shi'a, believed that only individuals with direct lineage to the Prophet could guide the Muslim community righteously. They thought that 'Ali, Muhammad's closest surviving blood male relative, should be their next leader ( caliph ). The other faction, the Sunnis, believed that the Prophet's successor should be determined by consensus and successively elected three of his most trusted companions, commonly referred to as the Rightly Guided Caliphs (Abu Bakr, 'Umar, and 'Uthman), as leaders of the Muslim community; 'Ali succeeded them as the fourth caliph.

Today the Islamic community remains divided into Sunni and Shi'i branches. Sunnis revere all four caliphs, while Shi'is regard 'Ali as the first spiritual leader. The rift between these two factions has resulted in differences in worship as well as political and religious views. Sunnis are in the majority and occupy most of the Muslim world, while Shi'i populations are concentrated in Iran and Iraq, with sizeable numbers in Bahrain, Lebanon, Kuwait, Turkey, Pakistan, and Afghanistan.

Depictions of the Prophet Muhammad Featured in this unit are several depictions of the Prophet Muhammad. These portrayals, while somewhat rare, are not unheard of as there were (and still are) many different attitudes toward depicting the Prophet, and humans in general, in the Islamic world. These attitudes varied dramatically from region to region and throughout history; the societies that produced the works discussed here are among those that allowed the depiction of the Prophet. Commissioned by Muslims for Muslims, these images appear in biographies of the Prophet and his family, world and local histories, and accounts of Muhammad's celestial journey ( mi'raj ), as well as in literary texts. In each context, they serve a distinct purpose. They illustrate a narrative in biographies and histories, while in literary texts they serve as visual analogues to written praises of the Prophet. An image of the Prophet Muhammad at the beginning of a book endows the volume with the highest form of blessing and sanctity. Thus, illustration of him was a common practice, particularly in the eastern regions of the Islamic world (see also Frequently Asked Questions ).

  • Evidence Islam is Truth
  • The Benefits of Islam
  • Beliefs of Islam
  • How to Convert to Islam
  • Worship and Practice
  • The Hereafter
  • Stories of New Muslims
  • Comparative Religion
  • The Holy Quran
  • The Prophet Muhammad
  • Current Issues
  • Islamic History
  • Systems in Islam

Evidence Islam is Truth 159 articles

  • The Scientific Miracles of the Holy Quran 15 articles
  • The Scientific Miracles of the Prophet Muhammad Sayings 2 articles
  • Muhammad in the Bible and Other Scriptures 4 articles
  • The Authenticity and Preservation of the Holy Quran 21 articles
  • Evidence of Muhammad’s Prophethood 29 articles
  • Logical Proofs 45 articles
  • The Existence of God 62 articles

The Benefits of Islam 62 articles

  • The Door to Eternal Paradise 3 articles
  • Salvation from Hellfire 1 articles
  • True Happiness and Inner Peace 28 articles
  • Forgiveness for All Previous Sins 1 articles
  • Benefits to Society 15 articles
  • Benefits to Science and Civilization 7 articles
  • What Others Say about Islam, Muhammad, and the Quran 7 articles

Beliefs of Islam 211 articles

  • What is Islam 21 articles
  • The Six Pillars of Faith and Other Islamic Beliefs 49 articles
  • About God 63 articles
  • The Purpose of Life 22 articles
  • Stories of the Prophets 64 articles

How to Convert to Islam 13 articles

  • How to Convert to Islam and Become a Muslim 13 articles

Worship and Practice 115 articles

  • The Five Pillars of Islam and Other Acts of Worship 49 articles
  • Islamic Morals and Practices 66 articles

The Hereafter 35 articles

  • Paradise 8 articles
  • Hellfire 9 articles
  • The Journey after Death 12 articles
  • The Day of Judgement and Its Signs 9 articles

Stories of New Muslims 278 articles

  • Men 98 articles
  • Women 133 articles
  • Priests and Religious Figures 20 articles
  • Personalities 32 articles

Comparative Religion 160 articles

  • Jesus 59 articles
  • The Bible 21 articles
  • Christianity 26 articles
  • Mary 10 articles
  • Judaism 20 articles
  • Hinduism 5 articles
  • Buddhism 2 articles
  • Sikhism 2 articles
  • Scientology 2 articles
  • Tolerance in Islam 6 articles
  • Uncommon Faiths 17 articles

The Holy Quran 234 articles

  • The Authenticity and Preservation of the Holy Quran 26 articles
  • Structure and Attributes of the Quran 17 articles
  • Selected Topics from the Quran 25 articles
  • A Summary of the Quranic Chapters 123 articles
  • Essential Verses in the Quran 28 articles

The Prophet Muhammad 124 articles

  • Pearls from His Sayings 19 articles
  • His Characteristics 22 articles
  • His Biography 19 articles
  • Evidence of His Prophethood 29 articles
  • About His Sayings 15 articles
  • Stories of His Companions 22 articles

Current Issues 92 articles

  • Human Rights 14 articles
  • Jihad and Terrorism 2 articles
  • Women 39 articles
  • Islam and Non-Muslims 23 articles
  • Sects Attributed to Islam 14 articles

Islamic History 25 articles

  • In Brief 15 articles
  • In Detail 10 articles

Systems in Islam 77 articles

  • Family 18 articles
  • Politics 3 articles
  • Economy 11 articles
  • Justice 6 articles
  • Crime and Punishment 7 articles
  • Health and Nutrition 19 articles
  • The Environment 13 articles
  • Islamic Songs (Nasheed)
  • New Muslims
  • Short Videos About Islam

Evidence Islam is Truth 122 videos

  • The Scientific Miracles of the Holy Quran 17 videos
  • The Scientific Miracles of the Prophet Muhammad Sayings 2 videos
  • Muhammad in the Bible and Other Scriptures 2 videos
  • The Authenticity and Preservation of the Holy Quran 25 videos
  • Evidence of Muhammad’s Prophethood 6 videos
  • Logical Proofs 33 videos
  • The Existence of God 38 videos

The Benefits of Islam 102 videos

  • The Door to Eternal Paradise 3 videos
  • Salvation from Hellfire 6 videos
  • True Happiness and Inner Peace 36 videos
  • Benefits to Society 39 videos
  • Benefits to Science and Civilization 13 videos
  • What Others Say about Islam, Muhammad, and the Quran 6 videos

Beliefs of Islam 176 videos

  • What is Islam 43 videos
  • The Six Pillars of Faith and Other Islamic Beliefs 37 videos
  • About God 53 videos
  • The Purpose of Life 24 videos
  • Stories of the Prophets 15 videos

How to Convert to Islam 8 videos

  • How to Convert to Islam and Become a Muslim 8 videos

Worship and Practice 16 videos

  • The Five Pillars of Islam and Other Acts of Worship 7 videos
  • Islamic Morals and Practices 8 videos

The Hereafter 17 videos

  • Paradise 3 videos
  • Hellfire 2 videos
  • The Journey after Death 5 videos
  • The Day of Judgement and Its Signs 8 videos

Stories of New Muslims 235 videos

  • Men 180 videos
  • Women 34 videos
  • Priests and Religious Figures 5 videos
  • Personalities 18 videos

Comparative Religion 123 videos

  • Jesus 65 videos
  • The Bible 20 videos
  • Christianity 27 videos
  • Mary 2 videos
  • Judaism 6 videos
  • Tolerance in Islam 9 videos

The Holy Quran 51 videos

  • The Scientific Miracles of the Holy Quran 9 videos
  • The Authenticity and Preservation of the Holy Quran 31 videos
  • Jewels from the Quran 7 videos
  • A Summary of the Meanings of Its Verses 1 videos

The Prophet Muhammad 71 videos

  • Pearls from His Sayings 2 videos
  • His Characteristics 32 videos
  • His Biography 21 videos
  • Evidence of His Prophethood 9 videos
  • About His Sayings 1 videos
  • Stories of His Companions 5 videos

Current Issues 64 videos

  • Human Rights 14 videos
  • Jihad and Terrorism 30 videos
  • Women 20 videos
  • Islam and Non-Muslims 10 videos

Islamic History 21 videos

  • In Brief 3 videos
  • In Detail 18 videos

Systems in Islam 25 videos

  • Family 4 videos
  • Politics 1 videos
  • Economy 2 videos
  • Justice 13 videos
  • Crime and Punishment 2 videos
  • Health and Nutrition 3 videos

Islamic Songs (Nasheed) 14 videos

  • NBN Band 1 videos
  • Zain Bhikha 1 videos
  • Ahmad Bukhatir 2 videos
  • Yusuf Islam (Cat Stevens) 2 videos
  • Kamal Uddin 2 videos
  • Labbayk 1 videos
  • TalkIslam 2 videos

New Muslims 148 videos

  • Merits of Islam 8 videos
  • Islamic Beliefs 11 videos
  • Acts of Worship 27 videos
  • Islamic Lifestyle, Morals and Practices 23 videos
  • The Holy Quran 11 videos
  • Prophet Muhammad 32 videos
  • Social Interaction 22 videos
  • Increasing faith 23 videos

Short Videos About Islam 26 videos

  • Islam in 3 Minutes 18 videos
  • Understanding Islam By Yusuf Estes 8 videos

Islam at a Glance

  • Intro E-books

Spread of Islam in West Africa (part 1 of 3): The Empire of Ghana

Description: how islam spread into sub-saharan region of west africa, and the great civilizations it established there, taking its inhabitants out of paganism to the worship of one god.  part 1: islam reaches west africa, and a history of the islamic empire of ghana..

  • By Prof. A. Rahman I. Doi
  • Published on 10 Apr 2006
  • Last modified on 14 Oct 2021
  • Printed: 4,436
  • Viewed: 465,543 (daily average: 69)
  • Rating: 2.7 out of 5
  • Rated by: 110
  • Emailed: 35
  • Commented on: 3

Spread_of_Islam_in_West_Africa_(part_1_of_3)_001.jpg

Eminent Arab historians and African scholars have written on the empires of Ghana, Mali, Songhay, and Kanem Bornu.  They document famous trade routes in Africa - from Sijilmasa to Taghaza, Awdaghast, which led to the empire of Ghana, and from Sijilmasa to Tuat, Gao and Timbikutu.  Al-Bakri describes Ghana as highly advanced and economically a prosperous country as early as the eleventh century.  He also discusses the influence of Islam in Mali in the 13th century and describes the rule of Mansa Musa, whose fame spread to Sudan, North Africa and up to Europe.

Spread of Islam in West Africa

Islam reached the Savannah region in the 8th Century C.E., the date the written history of West Africa begins The Muslim-Arab historians began to write about West Africa in the early 8th century.  The famous scholar Ibn Munabbah wrote as early as 738 C.E., followed by Al-Masudi in 947 C.E.  As Islam spread in the Savannah region, it was quite natural that commercial links should also come to be established with North Africa.  Trade and commerce also paved way for the introduction of new elements of material culture, and made possible the intellectual development which naturally followed the introduction and spread of literacy, and for which parts of the Sudan were to become famous in the centuries to come.  In the Kingdom of Tekur, situated on both banks of the Senegal, Islam was accepted as early as 850 C.E., by the Dya’ogo dynasty.  This dynasty was the first Negro people who accepted Islam.

It was for this reason that Muslim-Arab historians referred to Bilad al-Tekur as ‘The Land of the Black Muslims.’  War-jabi, son of Rabis, was the first ruler of Tekur in whose reign Islam was firmly established in Tekur and the Islamic Shari’ah system was enforced.  This gave a uniform Muslim law to the people.  By the time the Al- Murabitun of Almoravids began their attack on Tekur in 1042 C.E., Islam had made a deep impact on the people of that area.  Al-Idrisi in 1511 described the Tekur Country as ‘secure, peaceful and tranquil.’  The capital town of Tekur was also called Tekur which had become center of commerce.  Merchants used to bring wool to sell there from Greater Morocco and in return, took with them gold and beads.

We have enough documents about the history of this region since it was known to the Arab historians as the Bilad al-Sudan, the land of the Blacks.  In the medieval period, the most well-known empires that grew there are known until our day: The empires of Ghana, Mali, Songhay, and Kanem Bornu.  Eminent Arab historians have written about the glories of these lands, notable among whom are Al-Bakri, Al-Masudi, Ibn Batutah and Ibn Khaldun.  Besides these scholars, there were local scholars whose works have come down to us.  As for example Tarikh al-Sudan , the History of the Sudan , by Al-Sadi and Tarikh al-Fattash by Muhammad al-Kati.

There were famous trade routes, like the one from Sijilmasa to Taghaza, Awdaghast, which led to the empire of Ghana, and another from Sijilmasa to Tuat, Gao and Timbikutu.  There were others which connected the present Nigeria with Tripoli via Fez to Bornu and Tunisia with Nigeria via Ghadames, Ghat, and Agades to Hausa land.  These routes had made all the above mentioned places famous trade centers.  These centers of trade invariably became centers of Islamic learning and civilization.  New ideas came through visiting traders in the field of administrative practices.  We shall study briefly the expansion of Islam in each of the ancient empires of Western Sudan.

Islam in the Ancient Empire of Ghana

Al-Bakri, the Muslim geographer, gives us an early account of the ancient Soninke empire of Ghana.  His Kitab fi Masalik wal Mamalik ( The Book of Roads and Kingdoms ) describes Ghana of 1068 as highly advanced.  Economically, it was a prosperous country.  The King had employed Muslim interpreters and most of his ministers and treasurers were also Muslims.  The Muslim ministers were learned enough to record events in Arabic and corresponded, on behalf of the king, with other rulers.  "Also, as Muslims, they belonged to the larger body politic of the Islamic world and this would make it possible to establish international relations."

Al-Bakri gives the following picture of Islam in Ghana in the 11th century:

The city of Ghana consists of two towns lying on a plain, one of which is inhabited by Muslims and is large, possessing 12 mosques one of which is congregational mosque for Friday prayers: each has its Imam, Muezzin and paid reciters of the Quran.  The town possesses a large number of jurists, consults and learned men.

Parts of This Article

Article

Add a comment

  • Country: Select Country Afghanistan Albania Antarctica Algeria American Samoa Andorra Angola Antigua and Barbuda Azerbaijan Argentina Australia Austria Bahamas Bahrain Bangladesh Armenia Barbados Belgium Bermuda Bhutan Bolivia, Plurinational State of Bosnia and Herzegovina Botswana Bouvet Island Brazil Belize British Indian Ocean Territory Solomon Islands Virgin Islands, British Brunei Darussalam Bulgaria Myanmar Burundi Belarus Cambodia Cameroon Canada Cape Verde Cayman Islands Central African Republic Sri Lanka Chad Chile China Taiwan, Province of China Christmas Island Cocos (Keeling) Islands Colombia Comoros Mayotte Congo Congo, the Democratic Republic of the Cook Islands Costa Rica Croatia Cuba Cyprus Czechia Benin Denmark Dominica Dominican Republic Ecuador El Salvador Equatorial Guinea Ethiopia Eritrea Estonia Faroe Islands Falkland Islands (Malvinas) South Georgia and the South Sandwich Islands Fiji Finland Åland Islands France French Guiana French Polynesia French Southern Territories Djibouti Gabon Georgia Gambia Palestine Germany Ghana Gibraltar Kiribati Greece Greenland Grenada Guadeloupe Guam Guatemala Guinea Guyana Haiti Heard Island and McDonald Islands Holy See (Vatican City State) Honduras Hong Kong Hungary Iceland India Indonesia Iran, Islamic Republic of Iraq Ireland Israel Italy Côte d'Ivoire Jamaica Japan Kazakhstan Jordan Kenya Korea, Democratic People's Republic of Korea, Republic of Kuwait Kyrgyzstan Lao People's Democratic Republic Lebanon Lesotho Latvia Liberia Libya Liechtenstein Lithuania Luxembourg Macao Madagascar Malawi Malaysia Maldives Mali Malta Martinique Mauritania Mauritius Mexico Monaco Mongolia Moldova, Republic of Montenegro Montserrat Morocco Mozambique Oman Namibia Nauru Nepal Netherlands Curaçao Aruba Sint Maarten (Dutch part) Bonaire, Sint Eustatius and Saba New Caledonia Vanuatu New Zealand Nicaragua Niger Nigeria Niue Norfolk Island Norway Northern Mariana Islands United States Minor Outlying Islands Micronesia, Federated States of Marshall Islands Palau Pakistan Panama Papua New Guinea Paraguay Peru Philippines Pitcairn Poland Portugal Guinea-Bissau Timor-Leste Puerto Rico Qatar Réunion Romania Russian Federation Rwanda Saint Barthélemy Saint Helena, Ascension and Tristan da Cunha Saint Kitts and Nevis Anguilla Saint Lucia Saint Martin (French part) Saint Pierre and Miquelon Saint Vincent and the Grenadines San Marino Sao Tome and Principe Saudi Arabia Senegal Serbia Seychelles Sierra Leone Singapore Slovakia Viet Nam Slovenia Somalia South Africa Zimbabwe Spain South Sudan Sudan Western Sahara Suriname Svalbard and Jan Mayen Eswatini Sweden Switzerland Syrian Arab Republic Tajikistan Thailand Togo Tokelau Tonga Trinidad and Tobago United Arab Emirates Tunisia Turkey Turkmenistan Turks and Caicos Islands Tuvalu Uganda Ukraine North Macedonia Egypt United Kingdom Guernsey Jersey Isle of Man Tanzania, United Republic of United States Virgin Islands, U.S. Burkina Faso Uruguay Uzbekistan Venezuela, Bolivarian Republic of Wallis and Futuna Samoa Yemen Zambia

(Not shown to the public)

Your comment will be reviewed and should be published within 24 hours.

Fields marked with an asterisk (*) are required.

Other Articles in the Same Category

Other videos in the same category.

Video thumbnail

Article Categories

Video categories, most viewed, editor’s pick, list contents, most popular, your favorites.

Your favorites list is empty. You may add articles to this list using the article tools.

Your History

Close

Retrieve Your Password

Forgot your password? No problem. Just let us know your email address and we will email you a password reset link that will allow you to choose a new one.

Registration

Why register? This web site has several customizations made specifically for you, such as: your favorites, your history, marking articles you have previously viewed, listing articles published since your last visit, changing font size, and more. These features are based on cookies and will work correctly only when you use the same computer. To enable these features from any computer, you should login while browsing this site.

The field(s) below are optional

Minimize chat

IMAGES

  1. The Spread of Islam in Africa (Illustration)

    how did islam travel to africa

  2. Islam in Africa

    how did islam travel to africa

  3. The Rise of Islam in Africa

    how did islam travel to africa

  4. Islam by Justin Sharma

    how did islam travel to africa

  5. The Spread of Islam 622

    how did islam travel to africa

  6. The Spread of Islam in Ancient Africa

    how did islam travel to africa

VIDEO

  1. False Myths Exposed: Islam in Africa 1

  2. How ISLAM spread into AFRICA?! #islam #muslim #explore #explorepage #africa #history #story #quran

  3. HISTORY

  4. The Arab Muslim Destroy Africa with Islam after Roman

  5. Islam in Africa (Overview)

  6. Rain on the N4 near Machadodorp

COMMENTS

  1. The Spread of Islam in Ancient Africa

    Article. Following the conquest of North Africa by Muslim Arabs in the 7th century CE, Islam spread throughout West Africa via merchants, traders, scholars, and missionaries, that is largely through peaceful means whereby African rulers either tolerated the religion or converted to it themselves. In this way, Islam spread across and around the ...

  2. Islam in Africa

    Islam in Africa is the continent's second most widely professed faith behind Christianity. Africa was the first continent into which Islam spread from the Middle East, during the early 7th century CE. Almost one-third of the world's Muslim population resides in Africa. Muslims crossed current Djibouti and Somaliland to seek refuge in present ...

  3. Trade and the Spread of Islam in Africa

    Multiple Trajectories of Islam in Africa Islam had already spread into northern Africa by the mid-seventh century A.D., only a few decades after the prophet Muhammad moved with his followers from Mecca to Medina on the neighboring Arabian Peninsula (622 A.D./1 A.H.). The Arab conquest of Spain and the push of Arab armies as far as the Indus River culminated in an empire that stretched over ...

  4. Spread of Islam

    The spread of Islam spans almost 1,400 years. The early Muslim conquests that occurred following the death of Muhammad in 632 CE led to the creation of the caliphates, expanding over a vast geographical area; conversion to Islam was boosted by Arab Muslim forces expanding over vast territories and building imperial structures over time. [1][2 ...

  5. Trade and Geography in the Spread of Islam

    In Appendix Table 2 Panel A, we report the summary statistics of the main variables employed in the cross-ethnic-group analysis. 11 An average ethnic group in the Old World has 21% of its population adhering to Islam in 2005, is 5, 230 kilometers from Mecca, and 1, 345 kilometers from trade routes before 600 CE.

  6. The Spread of Islam in West Africa: Containment, Mixing, and Reform

    Although European powers led to the decline of the Umarian state and the Sokoto Caliphate, colonial rule did little to stop the spread of Islam in West Africa. The British used anti-slavery rhetoric as they began their conquest of the Sokoto Caliphate in 1897. The Sokoto Caliphate ended in 1903, when British troops conquered the state.

  7. Western Africa

    The states of the Sudan. Western Africa - Muslim History, Culture, Traditions: A reasonable body of sources for the writing of western African history begins to be available about 1000 ce. Three centuries earlier the Arabs had completed their conquest of Africa north of the Sahara and so came into possession of the northern termini of trade ...

  8. PDF ISLAM IN AFRICA/AFRICANS AND ISLAM

    Scott S. Reese. rthern Arizona UniversityAbstractThis essay discusses some of the recent trends in the scholarship on Islam and Africa that contribute to a more nuanced understanding of the historical relationship between African M. slims and the global of believer.

  9. The African context: Islam, slavery, and colonialism

    The history of Islam in North Africa appears in conjunction with the history of the early Arab-Islamic conquests and the Ottoman Empire. However, the history of Islam in Africa cannot be separated from the interactions between Africa and the outside Muslim world, nor from its varied connections to Europe. Islam. Three themes define pan-African ...

  10. 8

    2 North Africa in the period of Phoenician and Greek colonization, c. 800 to 323 BC; 3 North Africa in the Hellenistic and Roman periods, 323 BC to AD 305; 4 The Nilotic Sudan and Ethiopia, c. 660 bc to c.ad 600; 5 Trans-Saharan contacts and the Iron Age in West Africa; 6 The emergence of Bantu Africa

  11. A deeper sense of Muslim Africa

    Ousmane Kane, the Prince Alwaleed Bin Talal Professor of Contemporary Islamic Religion and Society and professor of Near Eastern Languages and Civilizations in the Faculty of Arts and Sciences, will discuss his book, "Beyond Timbuktu: An Intellectual History of Muslim West Africa," at the Center for the Study of World Religions on April 3 at 5:15 p.m.

  12. How was Islam spread in Africa?

    West Africa felt the presence of Islam through North African traders who travelled with their camel caravans south of the Sahara. By the 14th century there were already Muslim sultanates in such areas as Mali, and Timbuctu in West Africa and Harar in East Africa had become seats of Islamic learning. Gradually Islam penetrated both inland and ...

  13. The History of Islam in East Africa

    Summary. The history of Islam in East Africa stretches back to around 1000 CE. Until the mid-20th century, it remained largely confined to the coast and closely bound up with the history of the Swahili towns situated on it. The Swahili language remains central to many East African Muslims, hence the occasionally heard phrase, "Swahili Islam.".

  14. Migration to Abyssinia

    The migration to Abyssinia (Arabic: الهجرة إلى الحبشة, romanized: al-hijra ʾilā al-habaša), also known as the First Hijra (الهجرة الأولى, al-hijrat al'uwlaa), was an episode in the early history of Islam, where the first followers of the Islamic prophet Muhammad (they were known as the Sahabah, or the companions) migrated from Arabia due to their persecution by ...

  15. How Timbuktu Flourished During the Golden Age of Islam

    For centuries, the city of Timbuktu, located in the center of present-day Mali in Western Africa, thrived as one of the bustling centers of culture and learning during the Golden Age of Islam. The ...

  16. Why Moroccan Scholar Ibn Battuta May Be the Greatest Explorer of all

    Upon leaving Africa, Battuta hatched a plan to travel to India, where he hoped to secure a lucrative post as a "qadi," or Islamic judge. He followed a winding route east, first cutting through ...

  17. Islam in Africa

    This chapter contains sections titled: Introduction. Factors Leading to the Spread of Islam in Africa. Influence of African Religions on Islam. Islam's Influence upon Africans 10. Islam and Education in Africa 13. Islam and Women in Africa. Female Circumcision (Female Genital Mutilation) Islam and Terrorism in Africa.

  18. Early Muslim conquests

    This is an accepted version of this page This is the latest accepted revision, reviewed on 8 September 2024. Expansion of the Islamic state (622-750) For later military territorial expansion of Islamic states, see Spread of Islam. Early Muslim conquests Expansion under Muhammad, 622-632 Expansion under the Rashidun Caliphate, 632-661 Expansion under the Umayyad Caliphate, 661-750 Date ...

  19. Mansa Musa (Musa I of Mali)

    Mali's Timbuktu was known for its schools and libraries. Mansa Musa (Musa I of Mali) was the ruler of the kingdom of Mali from 1312 C.E. to 1337 C.E. During his reign, Mali was one of the richest kingdoms of Africa, and Mansa Musa was among the richest individuals in the world. The ancient kingdom of Mali spread across parts of modern-day Mali ...

  20. The Prophet Muhammad and the Origins of Islam

    According to Islamic belief, Muhammad was the only person to see Heaven and Hell while still alive. After the Prophet's Death: Emergence of Shi'i and Sunni Sects of Islam. When Muhammad died in 632, he had not named a successor. One faction, the Shi'a, believed that only individuals with direct lineage to the Prophet could guide the Muslim ...

  21. Spread of Islam in West Africa (part 1 of 3): The Empire of Ghana

    Description: How Islam spread into sub-Saharan region of West Africa, and the great civilizations it established there, taking its inhabitants out of paganism to the worship of One God. Part 1: Islam reaches West Africa, and a history of the Islamic Empire of Ghana. Muslim geographers and historians have provided excellent records of Muslim ...